30.01.2013 Views

Trade and Employment From Myths to Facts - International Labour ...

Trade and Employment From Myths to Facts - International Labour ...

Trade and Employment From Myths to Facts - International Labour ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Trade</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Employment</strong>: <strong>From</strong> <strong>Myths</strong> <strong>to</strong> <strong>Facts</strong><br />

w is the nominal wage <strong>and</strong> L is employment. Bars indicate a floor for the wage<br />

<strong>and</strong> full employment for labour. Thus, if there is slack in the labour market such<br />

that L – L > 0, then the complementary condition holds as an equality, w – w<br />

= 0, <strong>and</strong> vice versa. This approach can be used <strong>to</strong> model the boundary between full<br />

<strong>and</strong> less than full employment scenarios.<br />

Another innovative example is <strong>to</strong> introduce labour unions in the labour market<br />

specification. Workers <strong>and</strong> firms can explicitly bargain over wages or employment<br />

levels, with the union setting the wage <strong>and</strong> firms making the employment decision.<br />

Unions may also decide <strong>to</strong> maximize employment subject <strong>to</strong> a minimum acceptable<br />

wage. A simple approach is <strong>to</strong> set up a monopoly model <strong>to</strong> endogenously define<br />

wage differentials <strong>to</strong> reflect union power as in Thierfelder <strong>and</strong> Shiells (1997).<br />

Structuralist models are useful for the analysis of labour market deregulation<br />

<strong>and</strong> its effects on wages, employment <strong>and</strong> incomes of the economy as whole. The<br />

fine structure of these models is unhappily beyond the scope of this chapter, but<br />

note in passing there is a fundamental property of CGE models that can be at seen<br />

as both a strength <strong>and</strong> weakness. Supporters of living wage, fair trade, better fac<strong>to</strong>ries<br />

<strong>and</strong> decent work initiatives can use CGE models <strong>to</strong> quantify the costs of these programmes<br />

in terms of the well-being of those left out of such programmes. Partial<br />

equilibrium models ignore the plight of rejected workers, but economy-wide models<br />

should not <strong>and</strong> often do not. Whether they fill the informal sec<strong>to</strong>r, return <strong>to</strong> school<br />

<strong>to</strong> acquire human capital, or enjoy their leisure time, these agents should be accounted<br />

for in the CGE. This may raise the cost of reformist policies <strong>to</strong> an unacceptable level,<br />

or the reverse, enable the political classes <strong>to</strong> make informed decisions about the cost<br />

of closing down “sweat shops” <strong>and</strong> the like.<br />

The above illustrates that labour markets can be modelled in a variety of ways.<br />

One of the main attractions of CGE models is that they can incorporate a wide<br />

variety of adjustment mechanisms in markets, ranging from the extremes of pure<br />

price or quantity-clearing markets <strong>to</strong> rationing, monopoly pricing, administered or<br />

foreign border prices. In any given model, a number of these adjust ment mechanisms<br />

can happily coexist, although subsequent interpretations of results can become somewhat<br />

opaque. It is, therefore, important <strong>to</strong> carefully chose labour market assumptions<br />

in accordance with the reality in the economy that is represented in the model.<br />

Making the right choice is particularly important in dynamic models. The impact<br />

on employment of trade depends on the assumptions made <strong>and</strong>, since the effects<br />

are cumulative in dynamic models, there is a risk of creating a cumulative implausibility.<br />

The choice of CGE model also matters. The original CGE models were all<br />

one-period set-ups for which comparative static changes (derivatives) could be computed.<br />

Many st<strong>and</strong>ard CGE models remain static owing <strong>to</strong> the great technical difficulty<br />

of inserting (many simultaneous) intertemporal optimization models in<strong>to</strong> a common<br />

framework. Once these formidable challenges have been met, however, they may still<br />

fail the test of plausibility, simply because their assumptions seem so unreal.<br />

Structuralist models deal with this problem by assuming simple s<strong>to</strong>ck-flow relation-<br />

96<br />

(w / w)(L – L) = 0 (3-5)

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!