28.11.2014 Views

RA 00048.pdf - OAR@ICRISAT

RA 00048.pdf - OAR@ICRISAT

RA 00048.pdf - OAR@ICRISAT

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Although those would appear to encourage a<br />

move towards more equal factor use ratios, it may<br />

well be that because of the poorly developed<br />

input support systems, there is often inequitable<br />

access, therefore preserving differences in the<br />

factor use ratios. However, even if this is the<br />

case, the solution may often be more with<br />

adjusting accessibility to the support systems<br />

rather than developing different improved technologies,<br />

but the difficulties of doing this should<br />

not be underestimated. 29<br />

Exchange or Market Systems<br />

for Inputs and Output<br />

The exchange and market systems are of crucial<br />

significance in determining the relevancy of particular<br />

improved technologies. The degree of market<br />

development is in turn influenced by a number<br />

of factors. All other things being equal, it is likely<br />

to be positively related to the level of development<br />

and negatively related to the physical<br />

distances to be covered.<br />

Because of constraints imposed by the lack of a<br />

marketing system, farming families are then<br />

forced to be self-sufficient. It is not surprising that<br />

a self-sufficiency orientation is often more pronounced<br />

in areas of low population density where<br />

high land/labor ratios prevail and the costs of<br />

market development per customer are therefore<br />

relatively high.<br />

The self-sufficiency orientation, usually implying<br />

an adaptation to low levels of production/income,<br />

is also an adaptation to the "costs" faced in<br />

exchanging goods and factor services. From the<br />

perspective of the self-sufficient farming family,<br />

these costs are deemed to be very high. For<br />

29. Because of limited resources, governments which<br />

usually provide such support systems find it difficult<br />

to provide them at the level that would be desirable.<br />

Consequently, access to such systems is often<br />

confined to the more influential and economically<br />

powerful farming families. Also problems are developing<br />

with the adoption of certain types of<br />

technology. For example, in Mali in recent years, the<br />

prices of cash crops have increased less rapidly than<br />

prices of animals and equipment (CRED 1976). Thus<br />

adoption of animal traction has slowed down creating<br />

an increasing dichotomy between those who<br />

already possess animal traction and those who do<br />

not (Ernst 1976).<br />

example, because of the effort required and low<br />

profitability levels, there may be little incentive to<br />

take small quantities of products to distant markets<br />

involving high transport costs in terms of<br />

money and/or time. Also, because of poor market<br />

integration, a strategy of producing cash crops<br />

may be perceived as too risky with too little to sell<br />

in drought years when food prices are also high.<br />

Nevertheless, seasonal hunger or the hungry gap<br />

which occurs at the beginning of the rainy season<br />

(Raynaut 1973) is still a major problem in many<br />

such areas but is probably often accentuated<br />

when market structures start developing and<br />

some reliance is placed on what is inevitably at<br />

the beginning a poorly developed and therefore<br />

inefficient system. The occurrence of the hungry<br />

season at such a time has a serious impact on<br />

labor productivity with a reduced calorie intake<br />

resulting in weight loss and reduced resistance to<br />

disease (Chambers and Longhurst 1979). Unlike in<br />

West Africa, where this hungry season occurs at<br />

the busiest time of the year, this period in India<br />

appears to be more common during slack periods<br />

in the agricultural cycle. In India, the inequitable<br />

land distribution and well developed labor market<br />

enables landless laborers to find work during<br />

active periods in the agricultural cycle.<br />

Costs and marketing risks decline with improvements<br />

in communications, transport, and market<br />

integration. For example, a drought affecting<br />

sorghum producers in the United States does not<br />

also raise their food prices, which are largely<br />

independent of growing conditions in sorghum<br />

producing regions. Low transport costs and high<br />

integration into the national and international<br />

market imply that developed country farmers<br />

produce almost exclusively for the market and are<br />

often more highly specialized than their counterparts<br />

in developing countries. SAT countries differ<br />

in the extent of market integration of their<br />

economies. In India, for example, there is a high<br />

degree of domestic market integration but a low<br />

degree of international market integration. In<br />

Thailand, there is a high degree of market integration<br />

both domestically (i.e., except for distant<br />

regions) and internationally, while integration is<br />

low in both areas in many parts of Africa. In<br />

general, however, the degree of market orientation<br />

and integration is rising everywhere. 30<br />

30. Although rising energy costs are causing setbacks in<br />

this trend particularly in thinly populated areas (e. g . ,<br />

areas away from the line of rail in Zambia).<br />

640

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!