04.10.2015 Views

ECONOMY

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

660 democratization<br />

that often drives this process. Conversely, agency-based explanations go a long way<br />

in analyzing the thrust and parry of the transition period, as multiple actors struggle<br />

for survival and dominance. Yet they have been aptly criticized for suffering “from a<br />

myopia of the moment” (Bratton and van de Walle 1997, 27) and lack of attention to<br />

the limitations and opportunities inherited from the past. One resolution has been a<br />

division of labor: “structuralist approaches are good at accounting for the general<br />

causes of regime breakdown and the consolidation of new democracies. Process<br />

approaches may explain the timing of breakdown and transition as well as the specific<br />

trial-and-error process of searching for a new viable regime” (Kitschelt 1992, 1029).<br />

Yet the most recent wave of democratization, which followed the collapse of Communism<br />

in 1989–91 in the Soviet Union and its east European satellites, shows that<br />

these two perspectives have much to contribute to each other. First, several structural<br />

preconditions inherited from the authoritarian regimes act to foster democratization,<br />

rather than constrain it. Moreover, elite agency matters long after the initial bargaining<br />

and well into the subsequent “consolidation” period. Second, elites can deliberately<br />

use these legacies to construct democratic regimes—subject to constraints from<br />

both elite competition and informal institutions. Third, the formal institutions of the<br />

state are as important as those of participation and electoral competition. Indeed, if<br />

there is a dominant lesson to be learned from the experience of post-Communism,<br />

it is that weak states threaten both democratic freedoms and the rule of law (e.g.<br />

Holmes 1997).<br />

2.1 Structures Enabling Elites<br />

First, both structure- and agency-based accounts tend to assume that structure constrains<br />

elites. It is only in moments of crisis that elites can act more freely. Yet if elite<br />

actors are the central agents of democratization, then where do their relative power,<br />

preferences, and strategies come from? Classifying elites “hardliners,” “softliners,”<br />

or “liberalizers” often leads to tautologies: the actors concluding the bargains are<br />

centrists, and we know they are centrists because they concluded the bargain. Just<br />

as importantly, why are some elites so much more successful than others in implementing<br />

their strategies?<br />

Post-Communist cases demonstrate that the key to elite action is their cognitive,<br />

organizational, and social endowments: skills and experiences, reputations, informal<br />

alliances and networks. Ironically, for the elites involved in democratization, these<br />

resources have their origin in the authoritarian anciens régimes and they can be used<br />

to facilitate or obstruct democratization. In central Asia, for example, regional leaders<br />

empowered by their control over scarce resources and, hence, ability to distribute<br />

patronage under Soviet rule dominated the negotiations for institutional change<br />

following the regimes’ collapse. Not surprisingly, facing almost no popular opposition,<br />

they opted to change little of the system with which they continued strongly to<br />

identify and from which they continued to benefit disproportionately (Jones Luong<br />

2002). But such elite endowments can also have more subtle effects: for example,

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!