04.10.2015 Views

ECONOMY

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

392 a tool kit for voting theory<br />

Figure 22.1a represent:<br />

Label Ranking Label Ranking Label Ranking<br />

1 A ≻ B ≻ C 2 A ≻ C ≻ B 3 C ≻ A ≻ B<br />

4 C ≻ B ≻ A 5 B ≻ C ≻ A 6 B ≻ A ≻ C<br />

To represent a profile for {Ann, Barb, Connie}:<br />

Number Ranking Number Ranking Number Ranking<br />

6 A ≻ B ≻ C 0 A ≻ C ≻ B 6 C ≻ A ≻ B<br />

3 C ≻ B ≻ A 2 B ≻ C ≻ A 6 B ≻ A ≻ C<br />

to elect a departmental chair, place the number of voters with each ranking in the<br />

appropriate ranking region: this equation 2 “Chair”profileisinFigure22.1b.<br />

As described in Saari (2001), the geometric representation sorts profile entries in<br />

a manner that simplifies tallying elections; e.g. as all voters preferring A ≻ B are to<br />

theleftoftheverticalline,theirsum6+0+6=12isA’s tally in the {A, B} election.<br />

This number, with B’s 3 + 2 + 6 = 11 tally from the right of the line, is listed under the<br />

edge. All pairwise outcomes are similarly computed with the outcomes listed near the<br />

appropriate triangle edge. According to these votes, Ann is the Condorcet winner—she<br />

beats all others in pairwise majority votes.<br />

Our standard voting system, where a voter votes for his favorite candidate and the<br />

candidate with the most votes wins, is called the plurality vote. But rather than voting<br />

just for one candidate, we might give 9, 7, 0 points, respectively, to a voter’s top-,<br />

second-, and third-ranked candidate. This is called a “positional election:” it is where<br />

the weights w 1 ≥ w 2 ≥ w 3 = 0 are assigned, respectively, to a voter’s top, second, and<br />

bottom “positioned” (ranked) candidates and the societal ranking is determined by<br />

the sum of points each candidate receives. Without loss of generality, scale all weights<br />

by dividing by w 1 to obtain (1, s, 0). So with the earlier 9, 7, 0 points assignment,<br />

the rescaling assigns 1, s = 7 , 0 points to a voter’s top-, second-, and third-ranked<br />

9<br />

candidate. To use weights that play a major role in what follows, the Borda Count is<br />

where 2, 1, 0 points are assigned to the candidates, so its scaled weights are (1, 1 2 , 0).<br />

The antiplurality vote, 1, 1, 0 (called this because by voting for two, you are effectively<br />

voting against someone), already is in scaled form.<br />

To compute tallies, notice that Ann’s outcome is [number of voters with A<br />

top-ranked]+ s [number of voters with A second ranked]. In Figure 22.1b, thefirst<br />

bracket’s value is A’s plurality outcome, or the sum of numbers in regions with A as a<br />

vertex: 6 + 0 = 6. The second bracket—the number of voters with A second ranked—<br />

involves the two triangles one step removed from where A is top ranked—the adjacent<br />

regions that both contain 6. ThusA’s positional tally is [6 + 0] + s [6 + 6] = 6 + 12s .<br />

All positional tallies are similarly computed and listed by the appropriate Figure 22.1b<br />

vertex. Readers unfamiliar with this process should experiment by computing election<br />

outcomes for other profiles.<br />

According to Figure 22.1b the plurality (s =0)rankingisC ≻ B ≻ A with a 9 : 8 : 6<br />

tally, so Connie, rather than Condorcet winner Ann, wins. But as the antiplurality system<br />

(s =1)hastheoppositeoutcomeofA ≻ B ≻ C with a 18 : 17 : 11 tally, Condorcet<br />

(1)<br />

(2)

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!