04.10.2015 Views

ECONOMY

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

onald rogowski 817<br />

Under the general principle of declining marginal productivity of each factor, MPL in<br />

each country decreases as the country’s population increases. Again before migration,<br />

the total product in country A is just the sum of all the marginal products, or the<br />

total area under the MPL curve; labor in country A receives its wage times its total<br />

labor, or the area of the darkly shaded left-side rectangle; owners of capital receive<br />

the remainder, or the area of the lightly shaded left-side triangle. Similarly labor in<br />

country B receives the area of the darkly shaded right-side rectangle, capital the area<br />

of the medium-shaded right-hand triangle.<br />

If labor can migrate freely between the two countries (and assuming that no capital<br />

moves with it), labor will flow from B to A (shifting the vertical line of division<br />

between the two countries to the right) until the wage is equalized in the two countries<br />

at w ′ . The wage in country A will fall, that in country B will rise; country A capitalists<br />

will benefit, country B capitalists will be harmed. But world production will increase,<br />

since after migration world product will include the diagonally striped center triangle<br />

that, before migration, was forgone. Hence migration, for the world as a whole, is unambiguously<br />

welfare improving. Exactly the same analysis would hold for movements<br />

of capital, save that ex ante capital would have the higher return in the less capitalabundant<br />

(i.e. poorer) country and would migrate from rich countries to poor ones.<br />

Less often noted, however, is that in advanced economies not just the wages of<br />

the unskilled, but per capita income, can fall as a result of migration and foreign<br />

investment; that is, the losses to the scarce factor can actually outweigh the gains to<br />

the abundant one(s). Again, this can readily be seen in the simple terms of Figure 45.1.<br />

Recall that total product in each country is the area under the MPL (marginal product<br />

of labor) line: the MPL tells us how much additional product we get from each new<br />

unit of labor, and the sum of all those marginal products is the total product. 4 Then<br />

per capita total product in each country is just that area under the MPL curve divided<br />

by the population segment (represented, remember, by the x-axis). This is the same<br />

thing as the average height of the trapezoid composed of (for our high-wage country<br />

in Figure 45.1) the medium-shaded triangle and the dark-shaded rectangle on the lefthand<br />

side. As population moves from country B to country A, per capita product—<br />

the average height of this trapezoid—must fall in A and rise in B. The point can be<br />

generalized: in the simplest Cobb–Douglas production function, with only capital<br />

and labor as inputs, per capita output y(= Y/L) is always increasing in the capital–<br />

labor ratio k(= K /L). 5 As trade in factors opens, capital-abundant countries export<br />

capital and import labor, decreasing k. Since, in the model, the marginal gain in<br />

productivity in the capital-scarce countries outweighs the marginal loss in the capitalabundant<br />

ones, world welfare improves; 6 but, in theory, developed-country welfare<br />

can easily decline.<br />

⁴ Similarly, if we graphed each student’s weight against her or his height, we would have a “marginal”<br />

curve; if we take the sum of all those weights—i.e. the area under the weight–height curve, or the<br />

cumulative distribution—we will know the total poundage of all students below a specific height.<br />

⁵ In the standard Cobb–Douglas notation, Y = AK · L 1−·; · O (0, 1); hence, where y = Y/L and<br />

k = K /L , y = Ak·. Whatever decreases the capital–labor ratio must decrease per capita output.<br />

⁶ In the notation used immediately above, dy/dk = A· ; i.e. the marginal per capita gain in output<br />

k 1−·<br />

from any given increase in the capital–labor ratio will be higher, the lower is the initial capital–labor<br />

ratio.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!