04.10.2015 Views

ECONOMY

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

910 economic methods in political theory<br />

and, therefore, is properly conceived as taking prices as given; in electorates, however,<br />

while it remains true that the likelihood that any single vote tips the outcome becomes<br />

vanishingly small as the number of voters grows, it is not true (at least for finite<br />

electorates) that the behavior of any given voter should be conditioned on the almost<br />

sure event that the voter’s decision is consequentially irrelevant. This is not usually a<br />

problem for classical collective preference theory which, as the name suggests, focuses<br />

on aggregating given preference profiles, not vote profiles. Nor is it any problem for<br />

Nash equilibrium theory insofar as there are a huge number of equilibrium patterns<br />

of voting in any large election (other than with unanimity rule), most of which look<br />

empirically silly. But empirical voting patterns are not arbitrary. And once account is<br />

taken of the fact that preferring one candidate to another in an election does not imply<br />

voting for that candidate (individuals can abstain or vote strategically), there is clearly<br />

a severe methodological problem with respect to analysing equilibrium behavior in<br />

large electorates.<br />

One line of attack has been by brute force, using combinatorial techniques to<br />

compute the probability that a particular vote is pivotal, conditional on the specified<br />

(undominated) votes of others (Ledyard 1984; Cox1994; Palfrey 1989). But this is<br />

cumbersome and places considerable demands on exactly what it is that individuals<br />

know about the behavior of others. In particular, individuals are assumed to know<br />

the exact size of the population. Myerson (1998, 2000, 2002) relaxes this assumption<br />

and develops a novel theory of Poisson games to analyse strategic behavior in large<br />

populations.<br />

Rather than assume the size of the electorate is known, suppose that the actual<br />

number of potential voters is a random variable distributed according to a Poisson<br />

distribution with mean n, wheren is large. Then the probability that there is any<br />

particular number of voters in the society is easily calculated. As a statistical model<br />

underlying the true size of any electorate, the Poisson distribution uniquely exhibits<br />

a very useful technical property, environmental equivalence: under the Poisson distribution,<br />

any individual in the realized electorate believes that the number of other<br />

individuals in the electorate is also a random variable distributed according to a<br />

Poisson distribution with the same mean. And because the number and identity of<br />

realized individuals in the electorate is a random variable, it is enough to identify<br />

voters by type rather than their names, where an individual’s type describes all of the<br />

strategically relevant characteristics of the individual (for example the individual’s<br />

preferences over the candidates seeking office in any election). If the list of possible<br />

individual types is fixed and known, then the distribution of each type in a realized<br />

population of any size is itself given by a Poisson distribution.<br />

The preceding implications of modeling population size as an unobserved draw<br />

from a Poisson distribution allow a relatively tractable and appealing strategic theory<br />

of elections. Because only types are relevant, individual strategies are appropriately<br />

defined as depending only on voter type rather than on voter identity. Thus individuals<br />

know only their own types, the distribution of possible types in the population,<br />

that the population size is a random draw from a Poisson distribution, and that all<br />

individuals of the same type behave in the same way. Call such a strategic model a

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!