04.10.2015 Views

ECONOMY

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

arry r. weingast & donald a. wittman 7<br />

The second type of institutional analysis utilizes the above methodology to make<br />

comparative statements about different institutions. For example, pivotal politics<br />

models show the differences in behavior between a unicameral majoritarian system,<br />

a bicameral system where each chamber uses majority rule, and a bicameral system<br />

in which one chamber employs a filibuster rule allowing a minority of legislators to<br />

prevent the passage of legislation. The first institution always results in the median<br />

legislature’s ideal policy. The second institution creates a gridlock range of possible<br />

policy choices—the set of points between the ideal policies of the median in each<br />

chamber. Any status quo policy in this set is an equilibrium in that there does not<br />

exist a majority in each chamber that can overturn it. The third institution extends<br />

the set of status quo points that cannot be overturned even further: the possibility<br />

of a filibuster means that only policies commanding 60 per cent in one chamber and<br />

a majority in the other can overturn a policy, so more status quo policies are stable.<br />

For a further discussion of these issues see Krehbiel (this volume) and Cutrone and<br />

McCarty (this volume).<br />

Third, a much smaller set of papers studies the structure of the legislature itself and<br />

treats its institutions as endogenous. 5 Four different approaches have been used to<br />

explain legislative structure: (1) legislator preferences, (2) committees as commitment<br />

devices, (3) parties as transactions cost reducers, and (4) committees as information<br />

providers. 6 We will now discuss each in turn.<br />

1.1 Legislator Preferences<br />

The simplest of the approaches bases legislative choice on legislator preferences<br />

and relies on the “majoritarian postulate,” which holds that legislative policy and<br />

procedural choices are made by majorities (Krehbiel 1991). In the context of<br />

one-dimensional models of policy choice, the preference-based approach has the<br />

following implications (Krehbiel 1993). First, policy choice corresponds to that of<br />

the median legislator. Second, suppose that legislators join one of two parties, and,<br />

further, that those to the right of the median largely join one party while those to the<br />

left of the median largely join the other party.<br />

Suppose that the status quo is to the right of the median and the proposed<br />

legislation seeks to move policy left toward the median voter’s ideal. The “cutting<br />

line” divides the set of voters into those favoring the status quo and those favoring<br />

the proposal. In this context, the cutting line is that policy halfway between the<br />

status quo and the proposed alternative (assuming that legislator utility functions<br />

are symmetric). Since the status quo is to the right of the median, so too will be the<br />

cutting line. The proposal makes every legislator to the right of the cutting line worse<br />

off, so they vote against the policy; while every legislator to the left of the cutting line<br />

is better off under the proposal and will vote for it.<br />

⁵ Weingast 2002 surveysthismodeofanalysisindifferent contexts. Shepsle (this volume) provides a<br />

variantonthesethemes.<br />

⁶ Laver (this volume) covers some of these issues; see also the summary in Shepsle and Weingast 1995.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!