04.10.2015 Views

ECONOMY

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

daron acemoglu & james a. robinson 679<br />

of manipulating future political power, and thus indirectly shaping future, as well as<br />

present, economic institutions and outcomes.<br />

We now show how, following Acemoglu and Robinson (2000, 2001, 2005), this<br />

general framework can provide a theory of the origins of democracy.<br />

3 ATheory of Democracy<br />

.............................................................................<br />

Democracy is a particular set of political institutions. Relative to some type of nondemocratic<br />

regime the key aspect of democracy is that it is a situation of relative<br />

political equality. 2 In a non-democracy some non-representative elite dominates the<br />

political institutions and this elite will use their power to make collective choices and<br />

economic institutions that benefit them. This elite is different in different countries.<br />

For example, in present-day China it is the Chinese Communist Party. In Burundi<br />

it is the Tutsi-dominated military. In nineteenth-century Britain it was the rich and<br />

landed aristocracy. In a non-democracy the preferences of most people are not taken<br />

into account in collective decision-making except to the extent that the disenfranchised<br />

can exercise de facto power.<br />

We can now consider how the framework we developed in the last section can<br />

be applied more specifically to think about the origins of democracy. Consider the<br />

simplest dynamic world we can imagine: there is a “today” and a “tomorrow,” and<br />

the elite, who control non-democracy, and the citizens care about both policies and<br />

economic institutions today and tomorrow. Suppose we are in a non-democratic<br />

society, which generally looks after the interests of the elite, and the citizens have de<br />

facto political power today. By this we mean that the disenfranchised have solved the<br />

collective action problem and can threaten to impose costs on the elite and in the limit<br />

depose it in a revolution. However, though the disenfranchised have de facto power<br />

today they are unsure whether they will have the same political power tomorrow.<br />

Given that we are in a non-democratic society, tomorrow the citizens may no longer<br />

have the same political power. Can they ensure the implementation of the policies<br />

and economic institutions they like both today and tomorrow?<br />

Imagine now that the citizens do not simply use their de facto political power<br />

today to obtain what they like now, but they also use it to change the political<br />

system from non-democracy to democracy. If they do so, they will have effectively<br />

increased their de jure political power in the future. Instead of non-democracy, we<br />

are now in a democratic regime where there will be voting by all. With their increased<br />

de jure political power, the citizens are therefore more likely to secure the economic<br />

institutions and policies they like tomorrow as well.<br />

² We do not distinguish between different non-democratic regimes (see Linz and Stepan 1996 for a<br />

typology). The nature of a non-democratic regime may be important for specific comparative static<br />

results but it does not alter the basic mechanisms that lead to the creation or consolidation of democracy<br />

(see Acemoglu and Robinson 2005, ch.4).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!