04.10.2015 Views

ECONOMY

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

352 the protection of liberty, property, and equality<br />

the court has deferred to the ostensible expertise and impartiality of the legislature by<br />

holding that any “conceivable” public purpose satisfies the “public use” requirement<br />

of the takings clause (Hawaiian Housing Auth. v. Midkiff, 1984). Thus property could<br />

be transferred from one party to another to break up a local monopoly or on tenuous<br />

findings of blight control. The thunderbolt in this area, however, was Kelo v. City<br />

of New London (2005) where a five-to-four majority of the Supreme Court upheld<br />

condemnation of private homes for economic development, which in turn provoked<br />

a firestorm of public protest and federal and state efforts to curb that limitless holding.<br />

The insecurity of property rights has increased political intrigue, and the use of<br />

restricted formulas for compensation has resulted in inefficient takings that have<br />

moved property from higher to lower valued uses. On these matters, some state<br />

courts, angered by high-handed local tactics, have taken a more restrictive view of<br />

public use under the analogous provisions of their own constitutions.<br />

Once the public use hurdle is overcome, compensation is owed when the state<br />

occupies all or part of a parcel of property. The theoretical ideal suggests that the<br />

compensation offered should leave the property owner indifferent between his former<br />

holdings and the state compensation package. The legal rules advance that goal in part<br />

by concentrating on the value of the property lost, and not that which is retained.<br />

In addition, most courts properly make adjustments for any gains or losses in the<br />

value of retained lands as a function of the taking, so that increased value from access<br />

to a highway will reduce compensation, while any impediment to retained land will<br />

increase it. But in calculating compensation, the legal rules that focus on the fair<br />

market value of the “property taken” will in practice fall far below this standard. The<br />

rules do not allow for any compensation of the owner’s subjective value because of<br />

distinctive uses or attachments to property. That restriction is defensible perhaps on<br />

the ground that subjective value is hard to measure. But even so, a small fixed bonus<br />

of, say, 5 or 10 per cent is administrable, and offers a serviceable proxy for these hard<br />

to measure elements of value. Less defensible than the subjective value rule are the<br />

exclusions of any costs of defending against the taking, doing appraisals, moving,<br />

and destroying good will. The upshot, however, is that the lax standards on public<br />

use and just compensation lead to too much taking activity. It has been sometimes<br />

suggested that individuals who are unhappy with these rules could purchase “takings<br />

insurance,” but the risk that the state would selectively condemn such insured lands<br />

makes it highly unlikely that any insurer would offer it, knowing that local political<br />

processes could target insured lands for government occupation or regulation.<br />

The second half of the takings issue involves regulatory takings, where the key<br />

question is whether any compensation is owed at all for “mere” use restrictions. Here,<br />

as noted, the lower standard of review means that many cases of value lost through<br />

regulation are treated as non-compensable. In Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon (1923),<br />

Justice Holmes famously held that a government was required to pay compensation<br />

when it required a mine owner to conduct his operations so as not to remove the<br />

support for the land and structures of the surface owner. The obvious defense of<br />

Mahon’s result was that the miner had purchased the so-called support estate from<br />

the surface owner, to whom he had to return it without compensation. But instead of

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!