04.10.2015 Views

ECONOMY

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

748 economic geography<br />

outcome—there would be oversupply of manufactures. Given the presence of agglomeration<br />

forces, what happens is that if one region gets just slightly ahead (perhaps<br />

by random chance) then cumulative causation forces take over. This region attracts<br />

manufacturing at the expense of the others, and is the only one of the New World<br />

regions to industrialize. The region also becomes more attractive for migrants, so<br />

attains larger population and economic size. The world supply of manufactures is<br />

then met by two clusters (Europe and northeast America) with the rest of the world<br />

specialized in agriculture, as in the example of the preceding sub-section. Comparing<br />

Argentina and the USA, North, Summerhill, and Weingast (2000) comment that “no<br />

deus ex machina translates endowments into ...outcomes;” in this simple story one<br />

does, and it plays dice.<br />

Of course, this picture is oversimplified. Competing regions are not identical<br />

ex ante; market size, location, endowments, and institutions are all important<br />

in determining the success of the modern sector. However, the insight from<br />

the theory is that even if differences in initial conditions are small, they may<br />

translate into large differences in outcomes. A small advantage can give a location<br />

the advantage of being the next to start industrializing. The industrialization<br />

processisthenrapid—a“take-off” as increasing returns and cumulative causation<br />

cut in. Furthermore, the industrialization of one New World region depresses<br />

the prospects for others, due simply to the overall supply of manufactures in the<br />

world economy. These other regions may experience failed industrialization, or industrialization<br />

that serves only the domestic market and remains internationally<br />

uncompetitive.<br />

4.3 The Spread of Industry: Globalization and Integration<br />

We outline one further application of this line of reasoning, extending the arguments<br />

developedabove.Asglobalizationreducestradecostsitbreaksdownsome(although<br />

not all) of the clustering mechanisms outlined in Section 3, thereby facilitating movement<br />

of industry to low wage regions. What form does this “spread of industry” take?<br />

More or less steady convergence, with most countries catching up at a steady rate,<br />

or alternatively rapid growth of some countries, while others stagnate? Comparison<br />

of east Asian performance with much of the rest of the developing world seems to<br />

support the former view, as does the empirical work of Quah (1997) pointingtothe<br />

development of “twinpeaks” in the world income distribution—an emptying of the<br />

low–middle range of the income distribution, as some countries grow fast and others<br />

are left in a low-income group.<br />

The economic geography approach to this should now be apparent, and was<br />

formalized by Puga and Venables (1999).Lettheworldbedividedbetweencountries<br />

that have manufacturing activity and those that do not. Some growth process<br />

is going on in the world economy—e.g. technical progress—which is raising demand<br />

for manufactures. This demand growth raises wages in the economies with<br />

manufacturing until at some point it is profitable for a firm to relocate; the cost

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!