04.10.2015 Views

ECONOMY

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

john duggan 79<br />

When the policy space is multidimensional, the task of equilibrium characterization<br />

is more difficult, and we simplify matters by specializing to the representative<br />

voter stochastic preference model. We say a policy x is a generalized median in all<br />

directions if, compared to every other policy y, thevoterismorelikelytopreferx to<br />

y than the converse: for every policy y, wehave<br />

Pr({Ë | u(y, Ë) > u(x, Ë)}) ≤ 1 2 .<br />

By strict concavity and our dispersion condition, if there is a generalized median in all<br />

directions, then there is exactly one, which we denote x „ . In the quadratic version of<br />

the model, x „ is equivalent to a median in all directions, in the usual sense. 11 When the<br />

policy space is multidimensional, such a policy exists, for example, if G has a radially<br />

symmetric density function, such as the normal distribution. This can be weakened,<br />

but existence of a median in all directions is quite restrictive when the policy space<br />

has dimension at least two.<br />

The next result provides a characterization of equilibria in the multidimensional<br />

stochastic preference model: in equilibrium, the candidates must locate at the generalized<br />

median in all directions. Under our maintained assumptions, a generalized<br />

median in all directions is essentially an “estimated median,” as in Calvert (1985), so<br />

the next result is close to a result contained in that paper.<br />

Theorem 9:(Calvert): In the representative voter stochastic preference model, assume<br />

vote motivation. There is an equilibrium (x ∗ A , x∗ B<br />

) if and only if there is a generalized<br />

median in all directions. In this case, the equilibrium is unique, and the candidates<br />

locate at the generalized median: x ∗ A =x∗ B =x „.<br />

As we have seen before, strategic incentives drive the candidates to take identical<br />

positions in equilibrium, but the implication for equilibrium existence in multidimensional<br />

policy spaces is negative, as existence of a generalized median in all<br />

directions is extremely restrictive.<br />

5.2 Win Motivation<br />

Under win motivation in the stochastic preference model, we again have discontinuities<br />

along the diagonal. Despite this, there is a unique equilibrium when the policy<br />

space is unidimensional, as with vote motivation, but now the characterization is<br />

changed. Let H Ï denote the distribution of the median ideal policy, i.e. H Ï (x) is<br />

the probability that the median voter’s ideal policy is less than or equal to x. Byour<br />

dispersion assumption, H Ï is strictly increasing and has a unique median, denoted x Ï .<br />

The next result, due to Calvert (1985), establishes that in equilibrium the candidates<br />

must locate at the same policy, the median of x Ï . Thus, in the unidimensional version<br />

¹¹ That is, every hyperplane through x „ divides the space in half: the probability that the<br />

representative voter’s ideal policy is to one side of the hyperplane is equal to one half.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!