04.10.2015 Views

ECONOMY

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

keith krehbiel 231<br />

No rolls<br />

Minority party rolls<br />

Majority party<br />

gatekeeping<br />

No rolls<br />

−1<br />

I<br />

0<br />

II III<br />

IV V VI<br />

1<br />

q<br />

2d − m<br />

d m r<br />

|d − m| |r − m|<br />

2r − m<br />

Fig. 12.4 Roll rate dependence on the distribution of the status quo<br />

is defined as the proportion of final-passage roll calls on which these conditions are<br />

met. A party with a low roll rate is presumed to have agenda power, while, conversely,<br />

a party that is rolled often is said to be weak.<br />

An immediate implication of the procedural cartel model is that a rational gatekeeper,<br />

in this case the majority party, is never rolled. Consequently its roll rate<br />

should be constant and zero. The minority party is expected to be rolled regularly<br />

because it has no presumed gatekeeping rights. In contrast, the median voter model,<br />

which Cox and McCubbins call the “floor agenda model,” implies that roll rates<br />

for each party will be a function of the distance between that party’s median voter<br />

and the legislature’s median voter. Cox and McCubbins then attempt to explain<br />

variation in roll rates via regression analysis. Let r and d respectively denote the<br />

majority and minority party medians, respectively. They estimate regressions of the<br />

form:<br />

Minority roll rate = · + ‚|d − m| + ε. (1)<br />

Majority roll rate = · + „|r − m| + ε. (2)<br />

The logic of the test is illustrated in Figure 12.4. Assume that at any given law-making<br />

opportunity, legislators’ ideal points are spread out over a finite interval, say [−1, 1].<br />

For ease of illustration, suppose the median of the minority party is d = −1/3, the<br />

chamber median is m = 0, and the majority party median is r =1/3. Reflection<br />

points 10 of the two parties therefore lie at −2/3 and2/3, and the policy space is<br />

conveniently partitioned into six segments, I–VI.<br />

Clearly, predicting roll rates under the cartel theory (or any given pivot model)<br />

requires assumptions about the distribution of status quo points. In the simplest case,<br />

suppose q is distributed uniformly over [−1, 1]. Then status quo points will arise in<br />

segmentsIorVIwithprobability1/6+1/6 =1/3. None of these status quo points<br />

elicit rolls, because majorities of both parties prefer the cartel-theoretic equilibrium<br />

as possibly amended. Accordingly, such votes are regarded as more appropriate grounds for inference<br />

than would be, say, procedural votes, frivolous amendments, etc.<br />

¹⁰ A reflection point of, say, a party median p with respect to the chamber median m,denoted<br />

R(p, m), is the point whose distance from p equals that between p and m butthatliesonthenon-m<br />

side of p. With distance-based (Euclidean) preferences, R(p, m) =2p − m. By construction the pivotal<br />

player with ideal point p is indifferent between m and its reflection point about p,i.e.R(p, m).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!