04.10.2015 Views

ECONOMY

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

daniel diermeier 173<br />

6 Non-cooperative Bargaining:The<br />

Question of Cabinet Stability<br />

.............................................................................<br />

After having tackled the problem of government formation, non-cooperative models<br />

were then applied to the issue of cabinet stability. A first connection was established<br />

by Lupia and Strom (1995) who proposed a game-theoretic model of cabinet termination<br />

by re-evaluating the key notion of “critical events” (Browne, Frendreis, and<br />

Gleiber 1984, 1986, 1988). Lupia and Strom suggested that external events should be<br />

interpreted as the input of a coalition bargaining process, representing each party’s<br />

outside option if the current government falls. Whether a cabinet terminates depends<br />

on the attractiveness of this outside option compared to each party’s payoff from the<br />

current government.<br />

This interpretation of the impact of random events marks a potentially important<br />

shift in the study of cabinet terminations. Cabinets are interpreted as equilibria of<br />

an underlying bargaining process that must be sustained over time as the political<br />

environment and thus the distribution of bargaining power among governing parties<br />

changes.<br />

The long-term impact of the Lupia–Strom model was mainly conceptual. The actual<br />

bargaining model is too simplistic to capture dynamics of coalition bargaining. 28<br />

Their approach demonstrated that what is needed is a multistage bargaining approach<br />

with an explicitly modeled stochastic process to capture the changing political environment<br />

that may lead to critical events.<br />

AfirststepinthisdirectionistheDiermeier–Merlomodel(DiermeierandMerlo<br />

2000). As in Lupia and Strom, Diermeier and Merlo conceptualize coalition governments<br />

as sustained equilibria in an underlying bargaining game. Bargaining is<br />

assumed to be efficient proto-coalition bargaining, similar to Baron and Diermeier<br />

(2001), but is now embedded in a multistage bargaining game with random shocks<br />

both to electoral prospects and to the parties’ reservation values. Such shocks may<br />

lead to the termination of government before the end of the game. In that case,<br />

a new cabinet would take office. Cabinets may avoid termination by redistributing<br />

(“reshuffle”) distributive benefits among the incumbent parties in response to<br />

external events.<br />

Government formation consists of two steps. First, a formateur is selected proportional<br />

to seat share. Then that formateur chooses a proto-coalition which is assumed<br />

to bargain efficiently. Any proto-coalition agreement needs to be approved by a<br />

chamber majority.<br />

Diermeier and Merlo are particularly interested in the study of minority government.<br />

They identify a government with an allocation of cabinet portfolios: a<br />

party that supports a minority government on critical votes but does not hold any<br />

portfolios is not part of the government, but is only part of the supporting coalition.<br />

Government policy is negotiated in the cabinet subject to majority approval<br />

²⁸ See Diermeier and Stevenson 2000; Diermeier and Merlo 2000.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!