04.10.2015 Views

ECONOMY

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

Weingast - Wittman (eds) - Handbook of Political Ecnomy

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS
  • No tags were found...

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

anna grzymala-busse & pauline jones luong 663<br />

1997). Where elites never faced a threat of replacement from a credible and wellorganized<br />

set of opposition forces, this despoilation could go on unchecked, as in<br />

central Asia (Jones Luong 2002). Indeed, the post-Communist context demonstrates<br />

that democratic contestation, rather than undermining economic reform, enables it<br />

(e.g. Hellman 1998;Fish1998).<br />

Representative elite competition, then, is one key to the successful introduction<br />

of both market reform and democracy (Grzymala-Busse and Jones Luong 2002).<br />

This is not simply a question of elite turnover, but of a mutual holding in check,<br />

and the generation of incentives to appeal to broader constituencies. This effect is<br />

predicated on the representativeness of elites, and on their contestation, not simply on<br />

fragmentation or divisions among elites. As both Latin American and African cases<br />

show, political fragmentation per se can pose major obstacles to economic reform. 4 In<br />

contrast, an active and well-organized opposition limits the excesses of the governing<br />

elites, by creating a credible threat of replacement to the government.<br />

2.3 The Roles of the State and Informal Institutions<br />

Both structure- and agency-based accounts of democratization have tended to focus<br />

on the formal institutions of representation and accountability. Given that without<br />

elections and contestation, we cannot speak of democratization, this is not an unreasonable<br />

emphasis. However, it overlooks the other institutional aspects of successful<br />

democratization: specifically, the role of the state and informal institutions.<br />

First, with few exceptions, the state has long been ignored in the study of democratization<br />

and of market reforms. 5 The emphasis has been on the pluralization of<br />

politics, economics, and civil society (e.g. Dahrendorf 1990;Fatton1999), rather than<br />

on the institutions of the state, such as centralized bureaucracies and the networks of<br />

security, redistribution, and market regulation, that they administer.<br />

Yet, the post-Communist experience demonstrates that the type and extent of state<br />

structures found in the countries undergoing transition profoundly influence democratization<br />

(e.g. Carothers 2002; Grzymala-Busse and Jones Luong 2002; O’Donnell<br />

1996). For example, a clear division between state and society generates powerful<br />

incentives both for elites to appeal to outside constituencies, and for these constituencies<br />

to hold elite despoliation in check. Moreover, the more the state had<br />

grown independent of the party during Communist rule, and the more it developed<br />

the capacity to administer (through implementing economic reforms, co-opting<br />

potential opposition, etc), the more successfully it could navigate the simultaneous<br />

transition to market and democracy. And a more apolitical state whose representatives<br />

have experience in administering liberalization has been a key contributor to the<br />

success of democratization.<br />

⁴ Similar arguments have been raised about the lack of reform progress in Ukraine (Motyl 1997).<br />

Haggard and Kaufman 1995 and van de Walle 1999 go as far as to argue that in these contexts, dominant<br />

party systems are more likely to initiate and sustain reform.<br />

⁵ These exceptions include Linz and Stepan 1996 and O’Donnell 1993.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!