06.06.2013 Views

STOCHASTIC

STOCHASTIC

STOCHASTIC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

detailed analysis of the qualitative behavior of portfolios consisting of a blend<br />

of one safe and one risky asset. Several ways to characterize portfolios are<br />

seen to relate to the absolute and relative risk-aversion indices. In Exercise<br />

CR-11, the relevance of absolute risk aversion to the problem of optimal<br />

insurance policies is outlined. Effects of changes in mean and variance of<br />

risky assets are examined in Exercises ME-3 and 4, in connection with the<br />

problem of optimal foreign exchange holdings. Exercise CR-17 presents an<br />

alternative approach to risk aversion, based on mean-variance indifference<br />

curves. In Exercises ME-8 and 9, additional results are presented regarding<br />

the effects of risk-aversion indices on the qualitative behavior of an investor's<br />

insurance premium as a function of mean and variance of risky return (see<br />

also Zeckhauser and Keeler, 1970). In Exercise ME-10 it is shown that a<br />

bounded concave utility function must have a relative risk-aversion index<br />

which increases "on the average," from values less than 1 for small arguments<br />

to values greater than 1 for large arguments. Exercise ME-23 presents a not<br />

commonly assumed utility function that has the desirable properties that it is<br />

increasing, bounded, strictly concave, and has decreasing absolute and<br />

increasing relative risk aversion. See Sankar (1973) for another desirable<br />

utility function. In Exercise ME-1 the reader is asked to devise stochastic<br />

dominance tests which would be appropriate to the class of utility functions<br />

exhibiting decreasing absolute or increasing relative risk aversion.<br />

III. Separation Theorems<br />

The Lintner paper discusses the application of mean-variance and safetyfirst<br />

analysis to portfolio selection. Under the assumptions that there exists a<br />

risk-free asset which can be lent or borrowed in unlimited amounts at a<br />

common positive rate of interest, the optimal portfolio problem becomes<br />

considerably simplified. Lintner proves a very important separation theorem<br />

due to Tobin (1958), which splits the computation into two parts. First, a<br />

single optimal mutual fund, the same for all investors, is calculated by solving<br />

a fractional programming problem. Then the optimal portfolio for any<br />

particular investor is calculated by means of a univariate unconstrained<br />

optimization. The Tobin-Lintner separation theorem implies that all investors<br />

will purchase different amounts of a common mutual fund, and this reduces<br />

the many-risk-asset problem to an effective single-risk-asset problem. If<br />

borrowing of the risk-free asset is limited, the separation theorem need not<br />

hold. In this case the computation of an optimal portfolio becomes considerably<br />

more difficult, and would generally need to be done separately for each<br />

investor's utility function. This is also true if the interest rate of borrowing<br />

exceeds that of lending. Some of the computational aspects of similar problems<br />

are treated in the Ziemba paper in Part III. The Lintner paper along with<br />

INTRODUCTION 85

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!