06.06.2013 Views

STOCHASTIC

STOCHASTIC

STOCHASTIC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

given parameter. Exercise ME-30 develops such results in the special case when<br />

the investor's utility function is a power or logarithmic function and it is<br />

optimal to invest in every available asset. For further results and information<br />

on this delicate topic the reader is referred to the discussion of the maximum<br />

theorem by Berge (1963) and to the work of Danskin (1967) and Hogan (1973).<br />

Not all distributions are "compact" in Samuelson's sense and the reader is<br />

asked to investigate the compactness properties of some common univariate<br />

distributions in Exercise CR-25. Samuelson's presentation does not delve<br />

deeply into many fine and subtle points of the analysis. The reader is therefore<br />

asked to provide some of this material and to verify some statements in the<br />

paper in Exercise CR-26. One can, of course, utilize Taylor series approximations<br />

for very general utility functions and random variables. In Exercise CR-2<br />

the reader is asked to calculate bounds in the maximum error in objective<br />

value terms using such approximations. Taylor series approximations of order<br />

n yield explicit deterministic polynominal functions of order n in terms of the<br />

wealth variable. However, in terms of asset allocation variables (Exercise<br />

CR-12) the approximation yields a sum of n signomial functions (i.e., signed<br />

products of positive variables raised to arbitrary powers) which reduce to<br />

polynomial functions only in very special cases.<br />

Samuelson's paper develops the notion that the mean and variance of wealth<br />

are approximately sufficient parameters for the portfolio selection model when<br />

the probability distribution of wealth is "compact." In the "compact" case,<br />

moments of order 3 and higher are small in magnitude relative to the first<br />

two moments of the portfolio return; hence a limiting approximation indicates<br />

that only the first two moments are relevant for optimal portfolio selection.<br />

Samuelson's presentation is heuristic. The paper by Ohlson presents a rigorous<br />

approach to the study of such approximations. Additionally Ohlson's analysis<br />

generalizes and extends the range of applicability of such asymptotic quadratic<br />

utility approximations. He shows that (essentially) it is sufficient if the third<br />

absolute moment vanishes at a faster rate than the first two moments, even if<br />

moments of order 4 and higher are infinite. Rather general utility functions<br />

also suffice, including the negative exponential, power, and logarithmic cases.<br />

The paper also discusses the specific case when the random returns have<br />

log-normal distributions, assuming that the mean and variance of the growth<br />

rates are linear in time. Such distributions are not "compact," yet the quadratic<br />

approximation is still valid. Exercise ME-31 illustrates a case where not all<br />

moments are finite, yet the asymptotic utility is a quadratic function of the asset<br />

proportions (see also Ohlson, 1974). For an alternative Taylor series justification<br />

for the validity of the mean-variance approximation in portfolio theory,<br />

see Tsiang (1972). Some discussion of Tsiang's paper appears in Borch (1974),<br />

Bierwag (1974), Levy (1974), and Tsiang (1974). See Chipman (1973) and<br />

Klevorick (1973) for a rigorous discussion concerning the existence of expected<br />

204 PART III STATIC PORTFOLIO SELECTION MODELS

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!