06.06.2013 Views

STOCHASTIC

STOCHASTIC

STOCHASTIC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Separation in Portfolio Analysis<br />

R. G. Vickson<br />

UNIVERSITY OF WATERLOO<br />

I. Introduction<br />

Most modern treatments of portfolio analysis are founded on the expected<br />

utility theory of von Neumann and Morgenstern [1]. When there is a single<br />

risky asset, expected utility maximization leads to a straightforward theory<br />

of demand for risk. In this case such questions as the demand for the risky<br />

asset as a function of wealth, of interest rate, and of taxation policies—in<br />

short, the microeconomics of risk—are all reasonably simple to analyze. This<br />

pleasant state of affairs generally breaks down if many additional risky assets<br />

are introduced into the problem. In the latter case the complexities of multidimensional<br />

nonlinear programming resist not only one's ability to calculate<br />

the optimal portfolio, but also one's ability to conceptualize the problem<br />

effectively. It is therefore important to know if the problem can be recast as<br />

a new problem involving only one or two "composite" assets, for if this is<br />

true the problem becomes effectively one or two dimensional. For example,<br />

if the optimal portfolio as a function of wealth leaves the risky asset proportions<br />

unchanged, the entire set of risky assets is effectively combined into a single<br />

mutual fund. The many-asset case is thus reduced to a single-asset case. In<br />

some circumstances, such a reduction to a single mutual fund might not be<br />

possible, but reduction to two distinct mutual funds might be. The many-asset<br />

case is thus reduced to a two-asset case—a significant reduction in problem<br />

size. A portfolio problem which collapses in this manner down to a problem<br />

involving one or two mutual funds is said to exhibit the separation property.<br />

Such problem behavior clearly has many advantages for both qualitative and<br />

quantitative purposes.<br />

In a recent paper, Cass and Stiglitz [2] have derived restrictions on the<br />

forms of utility functions which lead to separation of the portfolio problem<br />

for general markets. They find that only a very small class of utility functions<br />

allows general separation, these being the functions «(•) such that u'(w) =<br />

{a + bw) c or u'(w) = ae bw . It is well known that general (increasing, concave)<br />

utility functions lead to separation in the case of very special markets, having<br />

joint normal returns, in the presence of a risk-free asset which can be borrowed<br />

or lent without limit at a common interest rate (Tobin [3]; Lintner [4],<br />

3. SEPARATION THEOREMS 157

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!