06.06.2013 Views

STOCHASTIC

STOCHASTIC

STOCHASTIC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

investment returns are always nonnegative. Several common distributions<br />

might possibly be used to explain such security price changes. One such<br />

distribution that has some attractive analytic and methodological properties<br />

is the log-normal distribution. A variable has a log-normal distribution if its<br />

logarithm has a normal distribution. Many of the important properties of<br />

univariate and multivariate log-normal distributions are discussed in Exercises<br />

ME-20 and 21, respectively. Since log-normal variates are not closed under<br />

addition there does not appear to be an efficient method to solve portfolio<br />

problems that applies for general concave utility functions. However, for<br />

particular utility functions, one can develop approximations which have very<br />

attractive computational and qualitative properties. Such is the case when the<br />

utility function is logarithmic. Exercise ME-22 studies the qualitative properties<br />

of the optimal solution vector for this problem. Exercise ME-23 develops an<br />

approximating problem based on the assumption that the final wealth variate<br />

is log-normal. The approximating problem can be chosen from a surrogate<br />

family so that it has the remarkable property of possessing essentially all of<br />

the qualitative properties of the original problem. Moreover, the approximating<br />

problem is a single quadratic program, which may, as outlined in Exercise<br />

ME-24, be solved in an extremely simple way utilizing the Frank-Wolfe<br />

algorithm. Ohlson and Ziemba (1974) have developed similar results for the<br />

case when the investor's utility is a power function of wealth. Dexter et al.<br />

(1975) present computational results that support the approximation.<br />

III. Effects of Taxes on Risk-Taking<br />

The papers of Stiglitz and Naslund examine the effects of various taxation<br />

policies on an individual's risk-taking behavior. Stiglitz assumes that the<br />

investor is an expected utility maximizer, and analyzes the effects of taxation<br />

on the investor's allocation of wealth among a sure asset with nonnegative<br />

net return and a single risky asset with nonnegative gross return. There are<br />

assumed to be no borrowing or short-sale constraints. Stiglitz emphasizes<br />

two somewhat different measures of risk-taking: (1) the demand for risky<br />

assets, measured by the fraction of wealth devoted to the risky asset, and (2)<br />

"private risk-taking" (PRT), measured by the standard deviation of final<br />

wealth. He shows that a proportional wealth tax increases or decreases the<br />

demand for risky assets according as the Arrow-Pratt relative risk-aversion<br />

index increases or decreases with wealth, and that it increases or decreases<br />

PRT accordingly as the absolute risk-aversion index increases or decreases with<br />

wealth. Of more interest are proportional income taxes with various loss-offset<br />

provisions. A full loss-offset provision implies that the government shares the<br />

risks of loss as well as the potential gains. This reduces the variability of risky<br />

asset after-tax returns. Since the tax reduces expected return from riskless and<br />

212 PART III STATIC PORTFOLIO SELECTION MODELS

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!