06.06.2013 Views

STOCHASTIC

STOCHASTIC

STOCHASTIC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

172 BASIL A. KALYMON<br />

more general position compared to the extremes of the Weingartner [6] discounting<br />

method which uses the interest rate the firm will be paying on issued bonds, and the<br />

Pye [4] discounting scheme in which the precise realized single-period market rate is<br />

used. The discount factor as used in our model reflects the time preferences of the<br />

decision maker, recognizing the imperfections of the market which do not allow him<br />

complete flexibility in borrowing and lending. Such a discount factor would be affected<br />

by the market interest rate in as much as the latter contains information on future<br />

inflation, but would be principally determined by internal considerations. Note that<br />

the importance of this factor is deemphasized in the model in that it is used merely to<br />

compare different streams of interest payments and issuing costs and not to evaluate<br />

the utility of repayment of the principal. As noted above in this regard, the model<br />

assumes that the firm has already decided on the appropriate funding requirement in<br />

accordance with its investment opportunities. Current practice employs a single discount<br />

rate representing either a cost of capital or some type of single-period or multiperiod<br />

market rate.<br />

There has been little previous work in bond refunding as a multiperiod decision<br />

process. Weingartner [6] is the only one to explicitly formulate the problem as a<br />

multiperiod process. His model is completely deterministic, and assumes that a level<br />

debt will be maintained, with only a single bond outstanding at a given time. Pye has<br />

studied the use of a Markov process to represent interest rate fluctuation in [5], and<br />

has used such a representation in [4] to determine the value of the call option by assuming<br />

that a single refunding decision will be made in the most favorable period over the<br />

term of the issued bond. Also, Bierman in [1] has proposed using a Markovian representation<br />

of interest fluctuation to improve short-run timing when refunding a bond,<br />

but does not consider the full multiperiod implications. References for work on the<br />

term structure and fluctuations of interest rates may be found in Pye [5]. A summary<br />

of current practice, (using essentially single decision approaches) as well as a discussion<br />

of appropriate discounting rates to be used, can be found in Bowlin [2].<br />

The general model to be discussed is more precisely defined in §1, and the existence<br />

of optimal policies of special structure is proved in §2 under differing sets of assumptions.<br />

Calculation of optimal debt size after a decision to refund has been made is<br />

discussed in §3. In §4, simple necessary conditions for refunding are given for two level<br />

debt models.<br />

1. Model Formulation<br />

In this section, the basic model to be studied is formally defined. Let Di represent<br />

the net requirement for debt financing in period i, for i = 1, 2, • • • , n, with i = n<br />

representing the chronologically first period of the n-period planning horizon. The<br />

Di'a are assumed to be known. For additional clarification we stress that the financing<br />

requirement as used in our model represents the exogenously determined amount of<br />

debt financing which the firm envisions requiring. It is based on projected cash flows<br />

aggregated over all the major projects/investments of the firm. (See Footnote 1.)<br />

Let U , Xi and r, represent, respectively, the time to maturity, the size, and the coupon<br />

rate of the bond outstanding in period i. Let p,,m represent the rate of interest that<br />

must be paid on a bond issued in period i with time to maturity (or term) m. Defining<br />

Pi by pi = pi,*>, we shall define<br />

(1) Pi. = Vi(m, in),<br />

where Vi(m, p,) is an increasing function in pt. Thus !\(m, p.) represents the term-<br />

564 PART V. DYNAMIC MODELS

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!