06.06.2013 Views

STOCHASTIC

STOCHASTIC

STOCHASTIC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

(c) Can the result in (b) be true if E log XJX„ _ i < 0 ?<br />

(d) Provide a counterexample to the "false corollary": "If maximizing the geometric<br />

mean almost certainly leads to a better outcome, then the expected value utility of its<br />

outcomes exceeds that of any other rule provided it is sufficiently large."<br />

(e) Attempt to determine a method for constructing utility functions over final wealth<br />

that satisfy the false corollary. [Hint: Suppose U is bounded.]<br />

(f) Provide an example to verify the theorem in Section II.<br />

(g) Give an example of increasing inequivalent utility functions U and V that have<br />

distinct optimal strategies for specific Bernoulli investments.<br />

(h) Can the strictly concave assumption be dropped from the statement of the theorem<br />

in Section II?<br />

(i) Show that the almost certainly transitivity result in Section II does not hold if the<br />

time horizon is finite.<br />

(j) Refer to Section IV. What are the higher order terms in the Taylor series expansion ?<br />

When will they be "small" ?<br />

Suppose there are three investments having mean returns of (1.1,1.05,1.20) per dollar<br />

invested and variance-covariance matrix of returns equal to<br />

0.15 0 -0.2 \<br />

0.0 0 0.0 I<br />

-0.2 0 0.5 /<br />

(k) Compute Markowitz's efficient surface.<br />

(1) Compute Thorp's efficient surface.<br />

(m) Compare the surfaces.<br />

(n) Prove the lemma: An E log X optimal portfolio is never stochastically dominated.<br />

(o) Comment on the statement: "A characteristic of the Kelly criterion is that as risk<br />

decreases and expectation rises, the optimal fraction of assets to be invested in a single<br />

situation may become 'large'" in light of the fact that the optimal asset proportions,<br />

say A,, satisfy X, — .E(Ajr,/£Air,), where r, is the gross return from investment /'.<br />

22. This exercise presents an extension of Breiman's model to allow for more general<br />

constraint sets and value functions. The development extends Theorem 1 and indicates<br />

that no strategy has higher expected return than the expected log strategy in any period.<br />

The model applies to common investment circumstances that include borrowing, transactions<br />

and brokerage costs, taxes, possibilities of short sales, and so on. Suppose initially that the<br />

value function has stochastic constant returns to scale: VN = £f X^r*, as in Breiman's<br />

formulation. It will be convenient to utilize the superscripts N to denote the investment period<br />

under consideration. Let AN

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!