06.06.2013 Views

STOCHASTIC

STOCHASTIC

STOCHASTIC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

utility function. However, many concave utility functions may lead to the<br />

same optimal decision as that obtained by a given safety-first investor. When<br />

there is a risk-free asset the efficient surface is linear and the situation is largely<br />

indeterminate because the indifference surfaces are also linear. In Exercise<br />

CR-24 the reader is invited to show that these results also hold for a reformulated<br />

aspiration objective. The analysis also applies (Exercise CR-23) when the<br />

random returns have appropriate symmetric stable distributions instead of<br />

normal distributions and one utilizes a mean-dispersion analysis as discussed<br />

in Ziemba's paper. See also Exercise CR-21 for a related normal distribution<br />

case. Exercise ME-18 shows that the deterministic equivalent for the aspiration<br />

model that one obtains in the normal distribution case generally does not<br />

generate necessary nor sufficient deterministic equivalent sets when the returns<br />

have nonnormal distributions. Some properties of safety first like optimization<br />

problems are considered in Exercises ME-26 and CR-20. Exercise ME-2<br />

considers a chance-constrained programming problem and the utility function<br />

that it induces. Agnew et al. (1969), Ahsan (1973), Bergthaller (1971),<br />

Dragomirescu (1972), Levy and Sarnat (1972b), Pyle and Turnovsky (1971),<br />

and Telser (1955-1956) consider additional applications of chance-constrained<br />

programming to the portfolio selection problem.<br />

The paper by Ziemba is concerned with the expected utility portfolio model<br />

when the returns have Pareto-Levy distributions. These distributions are also<br />

termed stable because many of their members are closed under addition; they<br />

are of interest for the empirical explanation of asset price changes and other<br />

financial and economic phenomena. An important reason for this is that all<br />

limiting sums (that exist) of independent identically distributed random<br />

variables are stable. Thus it is reasonable to expect that empirical variables<br />

which are sums of random variables conform to stable laws. Stable distributions<br />

represent generalizations of the normal distribution and appropriate stable<br />

families are closed under addition. These distributions have four parameters.<br />

If two of these parameters (namely the skewness and characteristic exponent<br />

coefficients) are constant across investments, then a mean-dispersion analysis<br />

is consistent with the expected utility of wealth approach when preferences<br />

over alternative wealth levels are concave. The mean-dispersion analysis per se<br />

is considered in Exercise CR-7. In particular, if all means exist and are equal<br />

and investment alternatives are independent, then all optimal investment<br />

allocations are positive and are proportional to weighted ratios of the inverses<br />

of the dispersion parameters (as in the normal distribution case). A generalized<br />

risk measure and its properties are explored in Exercise ME-17. In order for<br />

expected utility to be finite it is required that for the large absolute values of<br />

wealth the utility function is not steeper than a power function whose order<br />

is not exceeded by the value of the characteristic exponent. Hence many<br />

common utility functions need to be appropriately modified since their limiting<br />

206 PART III STATIC PORTFOLIO SELECTION MODELS

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!