06.06.2013 Views

STOCHASTIC

STOCHASTIC

STOCHASTIC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

36 LELAND<br />

An alternative approach to proving the existence of optimal policies<br />

is to assign further properties to the preference ranking over actions, as<br />

reflected by the objective function. If these properties alone ensure<br />

existence, there is no need to incur the costs associated with bounding<br />

the action set.<br />

This paper considers a class of decision problems encompassing several<br />

of relevance to economists, including the choice of optimal portfolios<br />

and the choice of optimal inputs and outputs by a perfectly competitive<br />

firm (with constant or decreasing returns to scale) facing random prices.<br />

Weak, and indeed commonly assumed, properties of the utility function<br />

are shown to ensure the existence of optimal policies. Perhaps the most<br />

interesting implication of the results is that the perfectly competitive firm<br />

with constant returns to scale will have a determinate output when there<br />

is uncertainty regarding prices, and it has a risk-averse utility function<br />

over profits which is bounded above.<br />

II. A CLASS OF DECISION PROBLEMS<br />

The structure of a typical decision problem includes a set S of states<br />

of nature, a o--algebra Sf of events, a set C of outcomes (hereafter assumed<br />

to be in R 1 ), and a set D of decisions, each element of which.is characterized<br />

by a measurable function mapping 5 into C. In all decision<br />

problems, it is assumed that the decision-maker possesses a preference<br />

ranking over the elements of D. An optimal policy or action is defined<br />

as d* e D such that d* ~>d for all de D. Of course, such an action may<br />

not exist.<br />

The problems examined in subsequent sections are a special class of<br />

the general decision problem. As above, elements include a set of states<br />

of nature and associated u-algebra of events, and a set CC R 1 of outcomes.<br />

But the actions belong to a set X of feasible gambling positions in a set G<br />

of gambling opportunities.<br />

Each element g of the gambling opportunity set G is characterized by<br />

a measurable net return function mapping S into a set of monetary<br />

returns C" C R 1 . g(s), therefore, is the monetary return per unit of the<br />

gamble g, depending on the state of nature. If g(s) = k for all seS, the<br />

"gamble" provides a sure return k. We assume the following:<br />

CI G has a finite number of elements, g l ,...,g".<br />

G.2 G is independent of the actions of the decision-maker.<br />

G.l seems warranted, at least in the static case, by the finite number of<br />

stocks, bonds, products, etc., in which one can invest. G.l is a straight-<br />

PART III. STATIC PORTFOLIO SELECTION MODELS

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!