06.06.2013 Views

STOCHASTIC

STOCHASTIC

STOCHASTIC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

MANAGEMENT SCIENCE<br />

Vol. 14, No. 1, September, 1967<br />

Printed in U.S.A.<br />

EVALUATING A CALL OPTION AND OPTIMAL TIMING<br />

STRATEGY IN THE STOCK MARKET*<br />

HOWARD M. TAYLORf<br />

Cornell University<br />

The optimal strategy for the holder of a "put" or "call" option contract im<br />

the stock market is studied under the' random walk model for stock prices.<br />

Some results are distribution-free in that they depend only on the mean price<br />

change. Other results are derived under the assumption that price changes have<br />

a normal or Gaussian distribution. Under this assumption explicit results are<br />

obtained for the limiting case where the expiration date of the contract is indefinitely<br />

far in the future. Knowing the optimal strategy it is possible to<br />

evaluate whether the purchase of a given option can be expected to be profitable.<br />

1. Introduction and Summary<br />

A call is an option entitling the holder to buy a block of shares in a given<br />

company at a stated price at any time during a stated interval. Thus the call<br />

listed in the financial section of the newspaper as:<br />

U. S. Steel 49| 6 mos. $565.50<br />

means that for a price of $565.50 one may purchase the privilege (option) of<br />

buying 100 shares of the stock of U. S. Steel at a price of $49,375 per share at<br />

any time during the next six months. (Call prices listed in the newspaper are<br />

"asking" prices, and bargaining is often possible.)<br />

Of the many reasons for purchasing a call, two are studied here, referred to as<br />

the investor's problem (insurance problem [2]) and the speculator's problem. In<br />

the first case an investor may have decided to add a block of the stock of a particular<br />

company to his portfolio, leaving only the question of the timing of the<br />

purchase. He feels that in the near future the price of the stock may drop, enabling<br />

a more advantageous buy. However, not being sure and to guard against<br />

a near future price rise he purchases a call which guarantees that he, at least,<br />

need never pay more than the price stated in the call. Of course, should the price<br />

of the stock drop in the near future, he will ignore the call option and make his<br />

purchase at the lower price on the open market. As a current example (1966)<br />

consider the stock of American Telephone and Telegraph, one of the bluest of<br />

the blue chips, which is now selling at or near its lowest price in two years. The<br />

price is depressed because of a pending investigation of the company by the<br />

Federal Communications Commission, according to the financial newspapers.<br />

There is no doubt that the company is sound and soundly managed, and it is<br />

* Received May 1966 and revised January 1967.<br />

t In refereeing an earlier draft of this paper, Arthur Veinott made many detailed and<br />

helpful suggestions which resulted in simpler proofs under weaker assumptions with stronger<br />

conclusions. I thank him for his conscientious help.<br />

MODELS OF OPTION STRATEGY

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!