31.05.2014 Views

Processus de Lévy en Finance - Laboratoire de Probabilités et ...

Processus de Lévy en Finance - Laboratoire de Probabilités et ...

Processus de Lévy en Finance - Laboratoire de Probabilités et ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

3.4. CHOICE OF THE WEIGHTS 111<br />

Th<strong>en</strong> the sequ<strong>en</strong>ce {Q δ k<br />

αk<br />

} k≥1 where Q δ k<br />

αk<br />

is a solution of problem (2.27) with data C δ k<br />

M , prior<br />

P and regularization param<strong>et</strong>er α k chos<strong>en</strong> according to the discrepancy principle, has a weakly<br />

converg<strong>en</strong>t subsequ<strong>en</strong>ce. The limit of every such subsequ<strong>en</strong>ce of {Q δ k<br />

αk<br />

} k≥1 is a MELSS with<br />

data C M and prior P .<br />

The alternative principle of the preceding section does not carry over to non-attainable<br />

problems as easily and is not discussed here.<br />

3.3.3 Computing the noise level<br />

If the bid and ask prices are known, the noise level δ and an estimate of option prices C δ M can<br />

be computed directly using<br />

CM(T, δ K) := Cbid M (T, K) + Cask (T, K)<br />

, ∀ T, K,<br />

2<br />

δ := ‖Cbid M<br />

− Cask M<br />

Since for all i, the true option prices satisfy C M (T i , K i ) ∈ (C bid<br />

C M ‖ w ≤ δ.<br />

2<br />

‖ w<br />

.<br />

M , Cask M<br />

), we clearly have ‖Cδ M −<br />

If the bid and ask prices are unavailable, one can assess the or<strong>de</strong>r of magnitu<strong>de</strong> of δ directly<br />

from C δ M , using the following heuristic argum<strong>en</strong>t. Suppose that the exact data C M is attainable<br />

and that the errors in differ<strong>en</strong>t option prices are in<strong>de</strong>p<strong>en</strong><strong>de</strong>nt. Th<strong>en</strong> it is reasonable to assume<br />

that the main part of error, pres<strong>en</strong>t in C δ M<br />

will lead to violations of arbitrage constraints on<br />

option prices (e.g. convexity). Since the least squares solution Q + is an arbitrage-free mo<strong>de</strong>l,<br />

these violations of no-arbitrage constraints will contribute to the discrepancy ‖C Q+ − C δ M ‖2 w ≡<br />

ε δ (0), as shown in Figure 3.3. Therefore, ε δ (0) will have the same or<strong>de</strong>r of magnitu<strong>de</strong> as δ 2<br />

and one can approximately take δ ∼ √ ε δ (0). Since the noise level δ is only used to choose<br />

the regularization param<strong>et</strong>er α, we do not need to know it with high precision and this rough<br />

estimate is suffici<strong>en</strong>t.<br />

3.4 Choice of the weights of option prices<br />

The relative weights w i of option prices in the pricing error term (2.3) should reflect our confi<strong>de</strong>nce<br />

in individual data points, which is <strong>de</strong>termined by the liquidity of a giv<strong>en</strong> option. This

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!