31.05.2014 Views

Processus de Lévy en Finance - Laboratoire de Probabilités et ...

Processus de Lévy en Finance - Laboratoire de Probabilités et ...

Processus de Lévy en Finance - Laboratoire de Probabilités et ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

2.3. RELATIVE ENTROPY IN THE LITERATURE 77<br />

risk-neutral distribution of ass<strong>et</strong> prices.<br />

This prior must be updated to take into account<br />

the martingale constraint and the observed option prices, and it is natural to <strong>de</strong>mand that the<br />

updated distribution incorporate no additional information other than the martingale constraint<br />

and the pricing constraints. One must therefore minimize some quantitative measure of relative<br />

information of the two distributions, and it has be<strong>en</strong> shown (see [52]) that every measure of<br />

information satisfying a s<strong>et</strong> of natural axioms must be proportional to Kullback-Leibler relative<br />

<strong>en</strong>tropy.<br />

Because it only allows to reconstruct the ass<strong>et</strong> price distribution for one specified time<br />

horizon, and only takes into account the prices of options that expire at this horizon, Stutzer’s<br />

m<strong>et</strong>hod does not provi<strong>de</strong> any information about the risk-neutral process and thus cannot be<br />

used to price any <strong>de</strong>rivative that <strong>de</strong>p<strong>en</strong>ds on the stock price at times other than T . Avellaneda<br />

<strong>et</strong> al. [3] pursue the same logic further and propose a m<strong>et</strong>hod allowing to construct a discr<strong>et</strong>e<br />

approximation of the law of the process un<strong>de</strong>rlying the observed option prices. They consi<strong>de</strong>r<br />

N < ∞ fixed trajectories {X 1 , . . . , X N } that the price process can take, simulated beforehand<br />

from a prior mo<strong>de</strong>l. The new state space Ω ′ thus contains a finite number of elem<strong>en</strong>ts: Ω ′ =<br />

{X 1 , . . . , X N }. The new prior P ′ is the uniform law on Ω ′ : P ′ (X i ) = 1 N<br />

and the paper<br />

suggests to calibrate the weights (probabilities) of these trajectories q i := Q ′ (X i ) to reproduce<br />

mark<strong>et</strong>-quoted option prices correctly. Minimizing relative <strong>en</strong>tropy I(Q ′ |P ′ ) is th<strong>en</strong> equival<strong>en</strong>t<br />

to maximizing the <strong>en</strong>tropy of Q ′ and the calibration problem becomes:<br />

maximize −<br />

N∑<br />

q i log q i un<strong>de</strong>r constraints E Q′ [H j ] = C j , j = 1, . . . , M,<br />

i=1<br />

where H j are terminal payoffs and C j the observed mark<strong>et</strong> prices of M tra<strong>de</strong>d options. D<strong>en</strong>oting<br />

by g ij the payoff of j-th option on the i-th trajectory, and introducing Lagrange multipliers<br />

λ 1 , . . . , λ M , Avellaneda <strong>et</strong> al. reformulate the calibration problem as a minimax problem:<br />

⎧<br />

⎨ N (<br />

min max<br />

λ q ⎩ − ∑<br />

M∑ N<br />

) ⎫ ∑<br />

⎬<br />

q i log q i + λ j q i g ij − C j<br />

⎭ .<br />

i=1<br />

The inner maximum can be computed analytically and, since it is tak<strong>en</strong> over linear functions<br />

of λ 1 , . . . , λ M , yields a convex function of Lagrange multipliers. The outer minimum can th<strong>en</strong><br />

j=1<br />

be evaluated numerically using a gradi<strong>en</strong>t <strong>de</strong>sc<strong>en</strong>t m<strong>et</strong>hod.<br />

This technique (weighted Monte Carlo) is attractive for numerical computations but has<br />

a number of drawbacks from the theor<strong>et</strong>ical viewpoint.<br />

i=1<br />

First, the result of calibration is a

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!