01.05.2017 Views

632598256894

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

It is important to understand how capital structure impacts firm value and cost of capital in the ideal<br />

world created by Modigliani and Miller‟s assumption of perfect and frictionless capital markets. In<br />

this world capital structure is irrelevant, as firm value and cost of capital are not affected by capital<br />

structure. We all know, however, that M&M‟s ideal world doesn‟t exist. There are market<br />

imperfections and frictions, particularly income taxes and costly bankruptcy. By peeling back these<br />

assumptions, we can see how and why capital structure can impact both firm value and cost of capital<br />

in the real world.<br />

We will begin with income taxes, particularly the tax-deductible nature of interest expense.<br />

Deductible interest expense creates debt tax shields in any year equal to:<br />

where τ C is the corporate income tax rate, k B is the cost of debt, and B is the amount borrowed.<br />

As long as the firm is earning positive taxable income and paying income taxes, we can assume the<br />

yearly debt tax shield has the same risk as the interest on the amount borrowed, so k B is also the<br />

appropriate discount rate for the yearly debt tax shields. Assuming the cash flows are a perpetuity, the<br />

present value of the debt tax shield is:<br />

This debt tax shield decreases the amount of cash flow paid to tax authorities and therefore<br />

increases the cash flow available to debt holders and equity holders. With more cash flow available for<br />

investors, total firm value increases by the present value of the debt tax shield. In a world with income<br />

taxes and tax-deductible interest expense, M&M‟s Proposition I changes to:<br />

where V L is the value of the firm with financial leverage, V U is the value of the firm without<br />

financial leverage, and τ C B is the present value of the debt tax shield assuming perpetual cash flows.<br />

M&M‟s Proposition I now shows that the value of the firm with financial leverage is equal to the<br />

value of the firm without financial leverage, plus the present value of the debt tax shield.<br />

Income taxes and tax-deductible interest expense also change M&M‟s Proposition II. It is still true<br />

that increasing the use of debt finance (increasing financial leverage) increases the risk to equity<br />

holders and the cost of equity rises, but the Proposition II formula for cost of equity in this case now<br />

looks like this:<br />

The cost of equity is still a linear function of the firm‟s financial leverage, but the slope is not as<br />

steep. The increase in cost of equity, therefore, is not large enough to entirely offset the benefit from<br />

adding cheaper debt finance. In a world with income taxes and tax-deductible interest expense, an<br />

increase in the use of debt finance increases firm value and decreases the firm‟s overall cost of capital.<br />

If this were the only real-world condition that impacted firm value and cost of capital, the firm‟s<br />

optimal capital structure would be heavily weighted toward debt finance. In fact, clever financial<br />

managers would use as much debt finance as possible, as this would maximize firm value and<br />

minimize the firm‟s cost of capital.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!