01.05.2017 Views

632598256894

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Because leverage increases the riskiness of the cash flows to equity investors, leverage increases the<br />

cost of equity capital. But for moderate amounts of leverage, the impact of the tax shield on the cost of<br />

debt financing overwhelms the rising cost of equity financing, and leverage reduces the WACC.<br />

Economists Franco Modigliani and Merton Miller were each awarded the Nobel Prize in economics<br />

(in 1985 and 1990, respectively) for work that included research on this very issue. Modigliani and<br />

Miller proved that in a world where there are no taxes and no bankruptcy costs the WACC is<br />

unaffected by leverage. What about the real world, in which taxes and bankruptcy exist? What we<br />

learn from their result, known as the Modigliani-Miller irrelevance theorem, is that as leverage is<br />

increased WACC falls because of the tax savings, but eventually WACC starts to rise again due to the<br />

rising probability of bankruptcy costs. The choice of debt versus equity financing must balance these<br />

countervailing concerns, and the optimal mix of debt and equity depends on the specific details of the<br />

proposed project.<br />

Divisional versus Firm Cost of Capital<br />

Suppose the beer company is thinking about opening a restaurant. The risk inherent in the restaurant<br />

business is much greater than the risk of the beer brewing business. Suppose the WACC for the<br />

brewery has historically been 20%, but the WACC for stand-alone restaurants is 30%. What discount<br />

rate should be used for the proposed restaurant project?<br />

Considerable research, both theoretical and empirical, has been applied to this question, and the<br />

consensus is that the 30% restaurant WACC should be used. A discount rate must be appropriate for<br />

the risk and characteristics of the project, not the risk and characteristics of the parent company. The<br />

reason for this surprising result is that the volatility of the project‟s cash flows and their correlation<br />

with other risky cash flows are the paramount risk factors in determining cost of capital, not simply<br />

the likelihood of default on the company‟s obligations. The financial analyst should estimate the<br />

project‟s cost of capital as if it were a new restaurant company, not an extension of the beer company.<br />

The analyst should examine other restaurant companies to determine the appropriate β, cost of equity<br />

capital, cost of debt financing, financing mix, and WACC.<br />

Other Decision Rules<br />

Some firms do not use the NPV decision rule as the criterion for deciding whether a project should be<br />

accepted or rejected. At least three alternative decision rules are commonly used. As we shall see,<br />

however, the alternative rules are flawed. If the objective of the firm is to maximize investors‟ wealth,<br />

the alternative rules sometimes fail to identify projects that further this end and in fact sometimes lead<br />

to acceptance of projects that destroy wealth. We examine the payback period rule, the discounted<br />

payback rule, and the internal rate of return rule.<br />

The Payback Period

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!