27.02.2013 Views

EPA Review Annex Documents - DFID

EPA Review Annex Documents - DFID

EPA Review Annex Documents - DFID

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

creation) but can also lead to imports being diverted from more efficient sources as a result<br />

of the preferences granted (trade diversion). Whilst trade creation is welfare enhancing,<br />

trade diversion reduces global welfare. The net effect of a preferential agreement is then the<br />

balance between these two forces. However, the ambiguity of these trade effects extends<br />

also to the differentiated effect that these incur on actors in the economy. Whilst the welfare<br />

enhancing effects of trade creation on consumers are easy to grasp, the replacement of<br />

domestic production with imported goods is also likely to have negative effects on producers<br />

and possibly on employment. Similarly, the inefficient source switching due to trade diversion<br />

can have a positive effect on consumers who are now acquiring a good at a lower price than<br />

they were before the preferences where granted. 79 This suggests that quantifications of<br />

trade creation and trade diversion are to be interpreted with certain caution. 80 Adding to<br />

these effects, and of particular relevance to ACP countries given the importance of tariff<br />

revenue takings in overall government revenue, one must also consider the extended impact<br />

of loss of tariff revenue as a result of a reciprocal trade agreement. Given the importance of<br />

the EU as an origin market for imports and the possible scope for trade diversion, ACP<br />

countries will be vulnerable to strong budgetary constraints. Mitigating these is likely to<br />

require fiscal re-structuring.<br />

The dichotomy of the trade creation and trade diversion effects has been the rhetoric of<br />

preferential trade analysis for many years. However, it is important to note that it provides a<br />

diluted picture of the actual effects of a trade agreement. Recently, economists have begun<br />

thinking about the dynamic impact of trade liberalisation and more particularly the deep<br />

integration implications of trade agreements. Deep integration issues generally involve<br />

cooperation on competition policy; intellectual property rights (IPR); sanitary and<br />

phytosanitary (SPS) issues; technical barriers to trade (TBT); certification; standardisation;<br />

government procurement; services; rule of law and other such matters. These incur changes<br />

in the competitive and investment climate which can lead to increased productivity through<br />

exploitation of economies of scale or through technology transfers. They may also allow for<br />

increased fragmentation of production structures across national borders and can promote<br />

niche specialisation. These seldom understood effects are likely to be more welfare<br />

enhancing than the traditional effects of preferential liberalisation, yet they are harder to<br />

capture empirically.<br />

Whilst there is little by way of deep integration provisions in the <strong>EPA</strong> agreements, there are<br />

some loosely defined soft law provisions setting pathways for future cooperation. In this<br />

respect, the <strong>EPA</strong>s contain provisions for cooperation on SPS and TBT matters as well as<br />

talk of supra-national institutions that could harmonise regional standards. The effects of<br />

such provisions are hard to quantify but this is not a reason to ignore them. These are to be<br />

evaluated with respect to the cost of negotiation and the future potential gains that can be<br />

derived from these provisions.<br />

b. Methodologies Used to Assess Preferential Liberalisation<br />

Three widely accepted methods can be used for assessing the impact of preferential<br />

liberalisation. Each has its strength and weakness and the choice of one over the other will<br />

have consequences on the results obtained. Simulation models tend to be the preferred tool<br />

for the analysis of the <strong>EPA</strong>s. These can take on a Partial Equilibrium (PE) or a (computable)<br />

General Equilibrium (CGE) approach. The former has the advantage of quantifying the<br />

impact of changes in trade policy at the highest levels of disaggregation whilst the latter’s<br />

key strength resides in providing an approach which takes into consideration the<br />

transmission of price changes across the economy and across countries. ECA (2005) and<br />

79<br />

Trade diversion then becomes an opportunity cost of not engaging in multilateral liberalisation.<br />

80<br />

Furthermore, the trade creation and diversion effects will also depend on price transmission<br />

mechanism.<br />

32

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!