27.02.2013 Views

EPA Review Annex Documents - DFID

EPA Review Annex Documents - DFID

EPA Review Annex Documents - DFID

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

educed output for a period of time. Whilst it is difficult to grasp the magnitude of these<br />

adjustment costs, it is easier to approximate the compensation that would need to be<br />

disbursed by donors to compensate for these. Milner (2006) identifies the type and scale of<br />

the assistance needed to smoothen the transition period by separating it into five broad<br />

categories. The first category is the ‘fiscal adjustment’ cost which results from the loss in<br />

tariff revenue. Donors should focus efforts to enhancing tax collection methods from<br />

alternative sources. This can be done through technical assistance and capacity building<br />

programmes. The second type of assistance would treat ‘trade facilitation and export<br />

development’ in view of ensuring a swift re-allocation of resources towards more productive<br />

processes. This would require aid in the form of development of export products and<br />

enhancement of knowledge of export market opportunities. The third adjustment cost should<br />

focus on ‘production and employment’ where both workers and firms should be<br />

compensated in the form of unemployment benefits and training for the former, and<br />

production line restructuring for the latter. It then follows that donors should focus on ‘skills<br />

development and productivity enhancement’ to allow both firms and workers to reap and<br />

channel productivity gains. The last focus area is ‘negotiation and legislation’ where donors<br />

aid ACP countries in developing the capacity, through technical assistance, for negotiating<br />

trade agreements and for adapting existing legislations to changing demands. Whilst an<br />

estimate of these compensatory measures does not give us an idea of the real cost of<br />

adjustment, it provides an interesting benchmark of the costs that would fall on ACP<br />

countries in adapting to the new circumstances.<br />

Milner (2006) uses previous World Bank project budgets and available indicators (such as<br />

share of trade tax revenue in total tax revenue, or share of manufacturing in GDP) to make<br />

rough calculations on the scale of adjustment compensation needed by each ACP country.<br />

Overall, Milner’s results suggest that the fiscal adjustment category is the one that should<br />

attract most attention, closely followed by employment adjustment and skills/ productivity<br />

enhancement. In terms of geographical concentration of adjustment costs, he suggests that<br />

ECOWAS and ESA are to require the highest volumes of aid. Overall, Milner estimates the<br />

cost of adjustment assistance for ACP countries to be in the region of €9 billion at 2005<br />

prices. This figure would be in addition to the current funds available to ACP countries (€22.7<br />

billion for the years 2007-2013) 85 which would imply an increase in development funds just<br />

below 40%.<br />

In Table 2 the most important empirical studies carried out by region are mapped.<br />

Comments are made on the overall results and point the reader to the tables in the annex for<br />

a more in depth exposition of the methodologies and the results obtained from each<br />

empirical investigation.<br />

ECOWAS<br />

All empirical investigations suggest that trade creation will predominate over trade diversion<br />

in the ECOWAS region. Busse and Grossman (2004), by way of a partial equilibrium<br />

analysis, estimate that the share of EU imports will increase by 6% whilst the share of non<br />

preferential imports should increase by 3.5%. Under a similar partial equilibrium simulation<br />

but at higher degrees of disaggregation, Fontagne et al (2008) estimate that the long run<br />

impact on trading structures will increase ECOWAS exports to the EU by 4% whilst imports<br />

from the EU are set to rise by 15%. In terms of revenue lost due to loss of duties on EU<br />

imports, the empirical studies concur that this will potentially be a significant issue. Fontagne<br />

et al (2008) estimate that this loss could range between 38% and 27% of total tariff<br />

revenues. However, Busse and Grossman (2004) have a higher estimate of 53% of total<br />

import duties. This would represent a loss of 8% of government revenue which translates<br />

into a decline of 1% in GDP. The countries that are most likely to be negatively impacted are<br />

85 http://ec.europa.eu/europeaid/how/finance/index_en.htm<br />

37

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!