27.02.2013 Views

EPA Review Annex Documents - DFID

EPA Review Annex Documents - DFID

EPA Review Annex Documents - DFID

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Caribbean and Pacific<br />

The impact of the <strong>EPA</strong>s on the Caribbean and the Pacific regions is likely to be of smaller<br />

magnitude than that in the SSA region given the small share of trade that occupies bilateral<br />

trade between the EU and these regions. Furthermore, most studies (Gasiorek et al (2006),<br />

Gasiorek and Winters (2004), Greenaway and Milner (2003) and Scollay (2002)) concur that<br />

trade diversion is likely to dominate over trade creation. In the Caribbean, Fontagne et al<br />

(2008) estimate the cost of losing Cotonou at 9% of exports to the EU, whilst they see the<br />

reciprocation of a signed <strong>EPA</strong> to add 25% to exports and 27% to imports to/from the EU.<br />

These values are to be interpreted from the perspective that the EU represents very little<br />

both as an overall destination and origin market. However, it is likely that there will be a large<br />

displacement of trade from more efficient sources to the EU. This carries not only the<br />

negative trade diversion effect, but also an important tariff revenue loss as customs duties<br />

on diverted dutiable sources are lost. Fontagne et al (2008) estimate the loss of tariff<br />

revenue falling between 16 and 13% whilst Gasiorek et al (2006) calculate a similar effect<br />

with import revenue falling 22%. In contrast, the PE model in Greenaway and Milner (2003)<br />

sees a reduction in customs taking of 73% in a scenario of full reciprocity. 88 Perez (2005)<br />

estimates this effect to reduce GDP by 0.2% under partial reciprocity (80%) and 0.5% under<br />

full reciprocity. In the case of the Pacific, very little empirical work has been carried out given<br />

the lack of data both for general equilibrium and partial equilibrium analysis however, Scollay<br />

(2002) argues that impact is likely to be small in magnitude and trade diverting at best. Perez<br />

(2005) estimates an overall reduction in GDP of 0.17% as a result of the <strong>EPA</strong>s whilst<br />

Fontagne et al (2008) claim an increase in exports from the region of 37% with no change in<br />

imports. In terms of tariff revenue loss, the study estimates a fall in tariff revenue of 8%<br />

whilst Perez’s (2005) results show a possible loss of 2.1% of GDP under a full liberalisation<br />

scenario and a fall of 1.6% of GDP if only 80% of tariff lines are liberalised. Milner Reflects<br />

this in his calculation of compensation accruing to the region where he calculates that the<br />

overall disbursement of aid to the region should be €0.6 billion to the Pacific and €0.9 billion<br />

to the Caribbean.<br />

In addition to the above table, it is also interesting to provide a graphical representation of<br />

the likely effects of the <strong>EPA</strong>s on ACP countries. In Figure 1 we do so by mapping, in the<br />

horizontal axis, the loss in tariff revenue as a percent of total tariff revenue and in the vertical<br />

axis we present the percentage change in trade balance according to the results in Fontagne<br />

et al (2008). Here we can easily identify the countries that are likely to suffer most in terms of<br />

revenue loss and also look at the change in trade balance as a result of the <strong>EPA</strong>s. Even<br />

though the position in the vertical axis is not a measure of welfare, it remains an interesting<br />

one as we can see how reciprocity also has its implications for exports of ACP countries. 89<br />

From the figure, we see how the GSP countries tend to be located in the upper part of the<br />

vertical axis whilst the EBA countries concentrate in the lower part of the axis. This follows<br />

the simple logic that GSP countries will receive, as a result of the <strong>EPA</strong>s, a greater<br />

preference margin given that the GSP regime has a lower coverage than the EBA regime.<br />

For countries falling into the EBA regime, there is little gain in terms of tariff preferences into<br />

the EU market as a result of the <strong>EPA</strong>s hence the effects of liberalisation will be concentrated<br />

on the import side. In terms of tariff revenue loss, we see from the figure that many EBA<br />

countries are located further out in the horizontal axis (Benin, Mali, Burundi, Burkina Faso).<br />

This suggests that many EBA countries will not only not gain much in terms of market<br />

access to the EU, but will also have to forego a sizeable chunk of their tariff revenue as a<br />

result of the <strong>EPA</strong>.<br />

88<br />

Greenaway and Milner (2003) use data for 1997 and at the 2-digit level. Given that there has been<br />

substantial liberalisation in the region since then, the results should be interpreted with caution.<br />

89<br />

The impact on exports of losing Cotonou preferences is often ignored in the literature, but not in<br />

Fontagne et al (2008).<br />

39

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!