27.02.2013 Views

EPA Review Annex Documents - DFID

EPA Review Annex Documents - DFID

EPA Review Annex Documents - DFID

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Fontagne et al (2008) argue that the ‘correct’ approach to be taken for this type of analysis<br />

should follow the CGE route however, the severe data limitations can make the PE approach<br />

more attractive. CGE models have strong data requirements which are often unavailable for<br />

individual ACP countries hence these models tend to group countries into regional<br />

aggregates and draw conclusions at a regional level (see ECA (2005) and Keck and<br />

Piermartini (2008) for a discussion). Further to this, the sectoral aggregation in CGE models<br />

using the GTAP database (version 6) is limited to 57 sectors. In contrast, PE models can be<br />

readily used for individual countries where disaggregated trade data is available and allows<br />

analysis at the highest levels of disaggregation (over 5000 products). Here however, the<br />

analysis is limited to the familiar Vinerian trade creation and diversion effects and also<br />

analysis of possible fiscal implications of liberalisation on a standalone basis. The main<br />

weakness of this type of model is that, unlike its CGE cousin, PE models do not take into<br />

account sectoral spillover effects and operate under a ceteris paribus assumption for each<br />

sector. A mitigating factor for using PE models, as argued by Fontagne et al (2008), is that<br />

the highly specialised nature of ACP economies in products differentiable only at high levels<br />

of disaggregation suggests that the CGE approach may miss important product specific<br />

effects. Another drawback of using the CGE approach is that results are likely to vary<br />

significantly depending on the closure used for the model. It is common to assume that<br />

labour markets clear, or that the balance of trade of developing countries stays constant;<br />

however whichever is chosen will impact the final results.<br />

Several key assumptions in simulation models are important to note. Firstly, it is often<br />

assumed that countries supply capacity is infinite and that changes in demand as a result of<br />

changes in preferences will be immediately met by countries. In the case of ACP countries, it<br />

is likely that this assumption does not hold, hence the effects of liberalisation, on the export<br />

side, might provide an upper bound potential rather than a true effect. Secondly, there tends<br />

to be an implicit assumption that changes in tariffs are directly transmitted to consumer. This<br />

is not always the case as it is possible that the rent created by the tariff reduction is kept on<br />

the exporter side rather than passed on to consumers. Another assumption that is commonly<br />

used is the Armington assumption of imperfect substitution, firstly across domestic and<br />

international sources and secondly across the different international origins. This assumption<br />

is a crucial one so as to avoid corner solutions and generally assumes that the elasticity of<br />

substitution between domestic and imported goods is lower than the elasticity of substitution<br />

across different origins for the imported goods. This assumption is very useful in that it<br />

allows one to move away from the homogeneous good assumption of past but it does not<br />

explicitly consider quality differentiation in goods trade.<br />

Regardless of the type of simulation model chosen to assess the impact of the <strong>EPA</strong>s, the<br />

crucial step in carrying out a good analysis is that of choosing an appropriate counterfactual<br />

scenario. The counterfactual scenario gives us a yardstick with which to compare the<br />

possible benefits of a change in preferences. A common mistake in the literature (ECA 2005)<br />

is that of choosing Cotonou preferences as the counterfactual scenario. 81 This is<br />

conceptually incorrect as the waiver received from the WTO for Cotonou preferences ended<br />

in January 2008 hence the more likely counterfactual would be reverting trade back to<br />

enabling clause preferences be these GSP or EBA. 82 Whilst for LDCs the changes from<br />

Cotonou to EBA are likely to have little to no impact in market access, the difference<br />

between Cotonou and GSP preferences is relatively large. Fontagne et al (2008) estimate<br />

that the loss of Cotonou preferences could reduce ACP exports by 4% where the impact is<br />

greatest for the COMESA region that could suffer a fall in exports to the EU of 12%. It is then<br />

probable that the impact of the <strong>EPA</strong> depends on the eligibility of ACP countries to EU<br />

unilateral preferences. GSP countries are likely to suffer most from the loss of Cotonou<br />

81 At the time the ECA (2005) study was carried out, there was great uncertainty as to the possible<br />

counterfactual solutions that would replace the <strong>EPA</strong>s if these were not signed.<br />

82 Perez (2005) uses a possible counterfactual of extending GSP+ concessions to all ACP countries.<br />

33

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!