10.04.2013 Views

FILSAFAT KORUPSI - Direktori File UPI

FILSAFAT KORUPSI - Direktori File UPI

FILSAFAT KORUPSI - Direktori File UPI

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

legal analysis, on the one hand, and the study of norms and public attitudes, on the other. Survey<br />

work from the region provides a fairly comprehensive picture of the attitudes of citizens and the<br />

managers of business firms in the post-socialist countries. This work also sheds some light on<br />

private sector and official behavior and on the nature of public and private institutions. Qualitative<br />

evidence from interviews and focus groups provides insight into the way households and businesses<br />

cope. Nevertheless, we know less than we would like about the actual operation of government<br />

institutions and about private sector organizations and informal groups. The rapidity of year-to-year<br />

changes leaves the analyst with questions about what has actually happened and unsure about the<br />

proper recommendations for reform. Most recent work shows a sharp divergence between the countries of<br />

the former Soviet Union (except for the Baltics) and those that came under Soviet influence only after the<br />

Second World War. There are exceptions and interesting cross-country variations, but as a general rule, the<br />

countries geographically closer to Western Europe are also closer to Western Europe in political,<br />

legal, and economic development than the countries farther east. This suggests that the most<br />

1 Henry R. Luce Professor of Law and Political Science, Yale University. I am grateful to Amnon Lehavi<br />

for very helpful research assistance. Parts II, III and V will appear in somewhat modified form in Kyklos<br />

54: 407-435 (2001). The comments of János Kornai and Margaret Levi are gratefully acknowledged.<br />

Page 2<br />

2<br />

pressing problems and their solutions will differ across the region. In some countries, growing<br />

poverty and inequality suggest a focus on simply avoiding collapse. Some of the laggards in the<br />

region, such as Russia and Ukraine, may need to go through a second transition to escape from<br />

dysfunctional traps where distrust in the state and in others builds on itself over time. In other<br />

countries, one can consider more fine-grained responses both to create institutions that facilitate<br />

trust and honesty and to help change public attitudes and expectations. Trust has many meanings. Part I<br />

distinguishes between three variants: generalized interpersonal trust, one-sided trust or reliability, and twosided<br />

reciprocal trust. It distinguishes between trust that arises from interpersonal interactions over time and<br />

trust based that arises from other sources. I argue that the development of legitimate, well-functioning<br />

governments and markets requires one-sided trust in public institutions. However, tensions can arise<br />

between one-sided trust in institutions and reciprocal trust in friends and family. In my view, the creation of<br />

generalized trust is a weak foundation on which to build a modern democratic market economy.<br />

Part II begins a presentation of data on the region. It reviews the survey evidence on public<br />

attitudes toward the state and on people‘s actual experience coping with state officials in Central<br />

and Eastern Europe. It documents the sharp differences between the western and eastern portions<br />

of the former Communist Bloc. Part III discusses the link between the creation of a trustworthy<br />

state and the role of participatory organizations and considers how these organizations might<br />

increase citizen trust and involvement. Part IV turns to business/state and business/business<br />

relations. It focuses not only on firms‘ relationships with politicians and bureaucrats but also on the<br />

way the law and the courts affect business to business dealings. The paper ends in Part V with<br />

suggestions for future research and policy analysis.<br />

I. Theoretical Foundations and Empirical Issues<br />

Trust implies confidence, but not certainty, that some person or institution will behave in an<br />

expected way. 2 A trusting person decides to act in spite of uncertainty about the future and doubts<br />

about the reliability of others‘ promises. 3 The need for trust arises from human freedom. As Piotr<br />

Sztompka (1999: 22) writes, ―facing other people we often remain in the condition of uncertainty,<br />

bafflement, and surprise.‖ Honesty is an important substantive value with a close connection to trust.<br />

Honesty implies both truth-telling and responsible behavior that seeks to abide by the rules.<br />

4 One may trust another 2 Russell Hardin‘s(2001: 10) view that trust is a type of knowledge or belief, not<br />

an action seems correct although in practice all one may be able to observe is the action that follows.<br />

3 Sztompka (1999: 25-40), Dasgupta (1988: 51). As Annette Baier (1986: 235) writes: ―Where one depends<br />

on another‘s good will, one is necessarily vulnerable to the limits of that good will. One leaves others an<br />

opportunity to harm one when one trusts, and also shows one‘s confidence that they will not take it.‖ Diego<br />

Gambetta characterizes trust as follows. ―Trust (or, symmetrically, distrust) is a particular level of the<br />

subjective probability with which an agent assesses that another agent or group of agents will perform a<br />

particular action, both before he can monitor such action (or independently of his capacity ever to be able to<br />

84

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!