09.11.2013 Views

PLANNING FOR A SUSTAINABLE EUROPE? - TU Berlin

PLANNING FOR A SUSTAINABLE EUROPE? - TU Berlin

PLANNING FOR A SUSTAINABLE EUROPE? - TU Berlin

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

45<br />

economies of scope, regarding transport investments. While somewhat doubtful<br />

empirically, such arguments would then call for a focus on intra-regional rather than<br />

inter-regional infrastructures, and for a redirecting of funds from Pan-European, largescale<br />

infrastructures towards locally-targeted, regional infrastructure investments. 2<br />

Concurrent with these observations, Van Geenhuizen and Ratti (1998:84) identify<br />

four basic forces that are reshaping the geopolitical and socioeconomic positions of<br />

European regions: 1) the unification of Europe (which resulted in an increased openness<br />

of regions), 2) the shift to a new local-global network economy, 3) the (related) rapid<br />

progress in information technology, and 4) policies for an environmentally sustainable<br />

growth (however these might be defined). The first three factors in particular lead to an<br />

increased competition between European regions and cities (Cheshire and Gordon 1995).<br />

Of course not everyone has drawn the same conclusions from the new realities unfolding<br />

around us. While everyone seems to agree that investments into physical rail and road<br />

infrastructures will remain crucially important even in the information age, opinions<br />

about investment priorities differ widely. This following section presents a general<br />

overview over theories on the economic aspects of transport investments.<br />

2 Not all scholars agree that flexible specialization is a necessary outcome, however. Capello and Gillespie<br />

(1993), for example, use a Regulation School underpinning to investigate spatial changes in Europe. They<br />

compare “the long-distance, regular, standardized commodity flow demanded by the (late) Fordist<br />

production system” with several future scenarios, notably Piore and Sabel's classic “flexible specialization”<br />

model of industrial organization and a “network firm/global-local” scenario. Interestingly, Capello and<br />

Gillespie (1993:58) raise doubts over “the over-idealistic view that a completely different industrial and<br />

spatial structure can be developed, with completely opposite features from those of Fordism.” They see the<br />

most likely future scenario in their own global-local model, where so-called network firms aim at<br />

“diversified mass production.” They conclude that “[w]ith respect to spatial organization, the outcome … is<br />

far less dramatic than the one suggested by [Piori’s and Sable’s] ‘flexible specialization’ scenario…. [I]t<br />

can be argued that the spatial extent of firms will remain … largely the same.” 2 The most serious drawback<br />

with Regulation school-type Post-Fordist scholars such as Capello and Gillespie, of course, is their often<br />

surprisingly narrow focus on the changing nature and re-organization of firms. Infrastructure decisions are<br />

then seen as simply following the (new or old) logic of capitalism, without much room for agency in the<br />

decision-making process.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!