13.07.2015 Views

Download the file - United Nations Rule of Law

Download the file - United Nations Rule of Law

Download the file - United Nations Rule of Law

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

The case for government or donor-funded legalinsurance is powerful in <strong>the</strong> presence <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> marketfailures described above, but it is important torecognise that such insurance is very expensive.It also involves significant redistribution <strong>of</strong> socialresources — not only from <strong>the</strong> well-<strong>of</strong>f to <strong>the</strong>poor, but among different sub-groups <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> poor.Subsidised legal insurance does nothing to mitigate<strong>the</strong> moral hazard problem, and it may erodeindividual’s incentives to take precautions to avoidbeing subject to legal action. Subsidised insurancealso reduces <strong>the</strong> incentives <strong>of</strong> marginally indigentindividuals to self-insure even when <strong>the</strong>y coulddo so (cf. H<strong>of</strong>fman, Rubin and Shepherd 2005).Moreover, although <strong>the</strong>re is no adverse selectionproblem under a universal insurance scheme— because opting out is impossible — <strong>the</strong> schemetransfers resources from people who rarely makeuse <strong>of</strong> emergency legal services to those who use<strong>the</strong>se services more frequently. Often this resourcetransfer takes <strong>the</strong> near-invisible form <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> opportunitycosts <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> resources spent on emergencylegal services for high-risk individuals and groups.Those resources might o<strong>the</strong>rwise have been spenton o<strong>the</strong>r legal or non-legal services that would benefitdifferent populations <strong>of</strong> poor individuals.This is not to say that state or donor provision<strong>of</strong> emergency legal insurance is a bad idea.Indeed, in some cases — such as <strong>the</strong> provision<strong>of</strong> competent criminal defence counsel free <strong>of</strong>charge to indigent defendants — state-fundedlegal insurance may be a moral and legal obligation.But because <strong>the</strong> operation <strong>of</strong> a universallegal insurance scheme is so costly, it is worthconsidering o<strong>the</strong>r techniques that reformersmight employ to redress <strong>the</strong> failures in <strong>the</strong> marketfor emergency legal insurance. One such approachis to expand <strong>the</strong> use <strong>of</strong> local communitybasedorganisations that allow individuals to pool<strong>the</strong>ir risk. For example, labour unions can — and<strong>of</strong>ten do — provide legal services on behalf <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong>ir members, especially to contest terminationdecisions and adverse employment conditions.Tenants’ associations can provide emergencylegal assistance to contest evictions; similarly,while landlords’ associations can <strong>of</strong>fer emergencylegal assistance to take action against unruly ordestructive tenants. The advantage <strong>of</strong> relying onsmall community-based representative groups toprovide emergency legal insurance is that <strong>the</strong>segroups may be better able to monitor and police<strong>the</strong>ir members and to apportion insurance costsin rough proportion to risk.The financing problem typically involves poorindividuals who have some legal claim — ei<strong>the</strong>ra positive legal entitlement or an injury to a legallyprotected interest — that has a positivemonetisable value that is greater than <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong><strong>the</strong> legal services necessary to pursue <strong>the</strong> claim.In an efficient market, because this claim has apositive net expected value, <strong>the</strong> individual shouldbe able to retain representation and receive anaward (perhaps through litigation, but more likelyin a settlement) that exceeds <strong>the</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> <strong>the</strong> legalservices. But in many cases poor individuals donot have <strong>the</strong> assets on-hand to pay <strong>the</strong> up-frontfees necessary to retain legal services in <strong>the</strong>private market (Yeazell 2006). Moreover, <strong>the</strong>irdisputes usually unfold with o<strong>the</strong>r poor peopleas defendants, and are mostly about division <strong>of</strong>property ra<strong>the</strong>r than damages. It is unlikely that<strong>the</strong>re is a ‘deep pocket’ around that can be <strong>the</strong>target <strong>of</strong> a claim. For <strong>the</strong>se reasons, <strong>the</strong> solutionthat <strong>the</strong>ir claim is financed by o<strong>the</strong>rs — by <strong>the</strong>irlawyer for instance — is usually not available.That being said, <strong>the</strong>re may be situations wherefinancing <strong>of</strong> claims is an option, such as in <strong>the</strong>case <strong>of</strong> personal injury arising from road trafficaccidents, and this will increasingly be <strong>the</strong> caseat higher stages <strong>of</strong> development. To that end gov-33

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!