08.06.2013 Views

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Rethinking</strong> <strong>the</strong> selfare state 118<br />

comprise housing and o<strong>the</strong>r living expenses that would o<strong>the</strong>rwise be borne by every<br />

individual with no disabilities. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, individuals who require institutional care<br />

will be responsible <strong>for</strong> paying <strong>the</strong> portion of <strong>the</strong> costs related to <strong>the</strong> non-service<br />

components of <strong>the</strong> care (shelter, food, etc.) ei<strong>the</strong>r on <strong>the</strong>ir own or with <strong>the</strong> assistance of<br />

social welfare or pension benefits, ra<strong>the</strong>r than through <strong>the</strong> tax-based system and LTC<br />

government assistance.<br />

Thus, <strong>the</strong> system would operate as follows <strong>for</strong> consumers of institutional care. <strong>The</strong><br />

cost of <strong>the</strong> care would be divided into two amounts, representing <strong>the</strong> service components<br />

and <strong>the</strong> non-service components. <strong>The</strong> service component would be financed in <strong>the</strong> same<br />

way that home-based care is financed—that is, <strong>the</strong> government will subsidize a certain<br />

percentage, and <strong>the</strong> individual will pay <strong>the</strong> remaining percentage through <strong>the</strong> tax-based<br />

collection system. Regarding <strong>the</strong> non-service component, <strong>the</strong> individual will bear <strong>the</strong> full<br />

costs independently of <strong>the</strong> health care system. However, low-income individuals may be<br />

eligible <strong>for</strong> subsidization of <strong>the</strong>se costs through social assistance or pension benefits.<br />

Normatively, <strong>the</strong> justification <strong>for</strong> drawing a dividing line between <strong>the</strong> service<br />

components and non-service components of institutional care is straight<strong>for</strong>ward.<br />

Taxpayers should not be required to pay <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> basic living expenses of LTC consumers<br />

under <strong>the</strong> guise of health care expenditures. <strong>The</strong> services that should be provided with<br />

some level of government assistance on a needs-tested basis are limited to those that are<br />

necessary <strong>for</strong> enabling individuals to per<strong>for</strong>m daily living tasks that o<strong>the</strong>rwise could not<br />

be per<strong>for</strong>med. Living expenses are properly subsidized by a means-tested social<br />

assistance program. In Germany, <strong>for</strong> example, <strong>the</strong> federal government is responsible <strong>for</strong><br />

LTC services, while local governments are responsible <strong>for</strong> social assistance. Thus,<br />

individuals who require financial assistance in addition to LTC benefits must apply to <strong>the</strong><br />

local government. 114 Ano<strong>the</strong>r policy reason <strong>for</strong> this division relates to horizontal equity<br />

among LTC consumers. Individuals receiving home-based services are required to pay<br />

<strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir own living expenses, and thus subsidizing <strong>the</strong> living expenses of those using<br />

institutional resources would create inequities in <strong>the</strong> treatment of <strong>the</strong> two groups.<br />

Moreover, by creating a windfall <strong>for</strong> individuals utilizing institutional care, perverse<br />

incentives would be created. LTC recipients would be encouraged to use higher-cost<br />

institutional care, even when <strong>the</strong>y are capable of remaining at home. From both a<br />

personal autonomy standpoint and an economic perspective, this is an undesirable result.<br />

Empirically, only two countries actually separate <strong>the</strong> medical and housing costs of<br />

LTC—Belgium and France. 115 Both operate successfully, fiscally and socially<br />

<strong>The</strong> successful operation of <strong>the</strong> proposed program requires that providers are able to<br />

freely enter and exit <strong>the</strong> market. For example, Hjertqvist reports that, in Sweden,<br />

“privatized nursing homes have reduced costs by 20–30 percent,” 116 suggesting that <strong>the</strong><br />

introduction of competition has increased cost-efficiency. Fur<strong>the</strong>r, it has been found that<br />

competition can also increase service quality. Zinn finds that when <strong>the</strong>re is greater bed<br />

availability in nursing homes (meaning that consumers have more options, and <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e<br />

that competition between providers is increased) <strong>the</strong>re are “fewer violations of nursing<br />

home licensure code requirements.” 117 This finding suggests that, “higher quality may be<br />

one outcome of increased competition.” 118<br />

However, concerns regarding <strong>the</strong> health and safety of beneficiaries mandate that <strong>the</strong><br />

government ensure that service providers are competent. To reconcile <strong>the</strong>se goals, it is<br />

necessary to establish a baseline set of requirements that providers must meet in order to

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!