08.06.2013 Views

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Rethinking</strong> <strong>the</strong> selfare state 26<br />

consumers may favour a different quality-cost trade-off than <strong>the</strong>ir proxy, yet possess no<br />

direct or effective means of asserting this preference.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, while Shleifer argues that private ownership tends to favour innovation,<br />

he does not distinguish between <strong>for</strong>ms of innovation which improve quality, and those<br />

which improve cost efficiency While it is true that in some services efficiency is a critical<br />

element of quality (consider, <strong>for</strong> instance, courier services, where faster turnaround<br />

benefits both customer and firm), <strong>the</strong>re are o<strong>the</strong>rs where more efficient service comes at a<br />

substantial quality cost. Consumers have an interest in having <strong>the</strong>ir preferences met; what<br />

better incentives does <strong>the</strong> contracting out of services give to providers to meet those<br />

preferences?<br />

This draws attention to ano<strong>the</strong>r set of contractibility problems. Let us assume, as is<br />

likely to be <strong>the</strong> case with respect to certain services, that <strong>the</strong> preferences of consumers are<br />

heterogeneous—that is, both varied and variable. <strong>The</strong> terms of a contract between proxy<br />

and provider can anticipate some of <strong>the</strong>se preferences ex ante; however, any significant<br />

change in preferences will effectively represent an uncontracted-<strong>for</strong> circumstance. <strong>The</strong><br />

residual control rights in such situations lie with <strong>the</strong> provider. This creates a principalagent<br />

divergence, since <strong>the</strong> agent has no profitable interest in meeting <strong>the</strong> demands of <strong>the</strong><br />

consumer (since <strong>the</strong> contract does not stipulate any remuneration <strong>for</strong> doing so, and <strong>the</strong><br />

consumer cannot censure an unresponsive provider by “unsubscribing”). As with purely<br />

public provision, supply-side subsidies provide no reliable incentive mechanism through<br />

which <strong>the</strong> consumer can influence directly <strong>the</strong> content of <strong>the</strong> market to meet his or her<br />

changing demands.<br />

Additionally, as Trebilcock notes, contracting out has <strong>the</strong> potential to create<br />

unintended but persistent monopolies:<br />

[T]here may be so much flexibility built into [a] contract that <strong>the</strong> firm can<br />

adapt to future changes in such a way as to exercise some monopoly<br />

power. <strong>The</strong> resulting bilateral monopoly becomes a more severe problem<br />

as <strong>the</strong> contract leng<strong>the</strong>ns in duration. [Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore,] incumbent contract<br />

holders often have a considerable advantage at renewal time over <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

competitors. Government will not want to cause a disruption by changing<br />

contractors. […] It is in a significantly better position at renewal time than<br />

its competitors who must start from scratch in bidding <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> contract<br />

renewal and must purchase all <strong>the</strong> necessary assets, often from <strong>the</strong><br />

incumbent if <strong>the</strong> assets are highly specific. 43<br />

Such de facto monopolies introduce <strong>the</strong> risk of driving prices back up above competitive<br />

levels, and may counteract <strong>the</strong> cost-effectiveness advantages imputed to supply-side<br />

subsidies in <strong>the</strong> first place.<br />

Finally, contracting out may invite problems of its own in some contexts. For<br />

example, Hart, Shleifer and Vishny view <strong>the</strong> objective function of a number of<br />

government activities as sufficiently complex or contingent that precise specification, by<br />

contract, legislation, regulation, or o<strong>the</strong>rwise, of objectives and ready monitoring of <strong>the</strong><br />

achievement of <strong>the</strong>se objectives are infeasible. 44 An extreme example is <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mulation<br />

and implementation of a country’s <strong>for</strong>eign or defense policy, where <strong>the</strong> complexity of<br />

objectives and un<strong>for</strong>eseeable contingencies render delegations of <strong>the</strong>se functions to

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!