08.06.2013 Views

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Legal aid 81<br />

• It limits <strong>the</strong> use of alternative mechanisms such as <strong>the</strong> contracting out of<br />

cases to private firms or lawyers.<br />

• <strong>The</strong> salary structure provides only limited incentives <strong>for</strong> maximum<br />

productivity on <strong>the</strong> part of staff lawyers.<br />

• Since <strong>the</strong> scale and nature of demand must be anticipated in order to hire<br />

adequate staff, staff lawyer programs may be inflexible in responding<br />

to changes in demand and, if located in central staff offices, unable to<br />

meet <strong>the</strong> needs of rural or remote communities. 22<br />

• It denies consumers <strong>the</strong> right to retain <strong>the</strong> counsel of <strong>the</strong>ir choice.<br />

An additional argument takes account of <strong>the</strong> principal-agent problem inherent in <strong>the</strong><br />

selection of counsel by <strong>the</strong> state on behalf of <strong>the</strong> individual citizen. As Charendoff et al.<br />

explain, “[i]t is argued that any staff system, even if <strong>the</strong> employer is at arm’s length from<br />

government, is inherently less able to ensure <strong>the</strong> independent legal advice which legal aid<br />

clients, in particular as <strong>the</strong>y are parties often adverse in interest to <strong>the</strong> state, should<br />

receive.” 23<br />

<strong>The</strong> crux of <strong>the</strong> problem in models of pure public provision is <strong>the</strong> lack of a purchaserprovider<br />

split. Most governments recognize that <strong>the</strong>re are perverse incentives embedded<br />

in a system in which <strong>the</strong> state both finances and delivers particular services. Indeed, New<br />

Zealand recently transferred control over legal aid from <strong>the</strong> Department <strong>for</strong> Courts to an<br />

independent legal aid agency, 24 as did <strong>the</strong> Canadian province of Ontario. Similarly, recent<br />

re<strong>for</strong>m initiatives in Nor<strong>the</strong>rn Ireland have focused on <strong>the</strong> “establishment of a new<br />

independent body to administer legal aid.” 25 <strong>The</strong> independence of such an agency is<br />

hoped to introduce a greater degree of impartiality and transparency into <strong>the</strong><br />

administration of legal aid. <strong>The</strong> report to Parliament states that “<strong>the</strong> Law Society will no<br />

longer be in a position where <strong>the</strong>y might be seen as having a conflict of interest between<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir responsibility <strong>for</strong> administering legal aid on <strong>the</strong> one hand and representing <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

members on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r.” 26<br />

Under arrangements where legal aid attorneys are employed by <strong>the</strong> state, <strong>the</strong> attorney<br />

has two allegiances: to her employer, <strong>the</strong> state, which has a fiscal interest in seeking a<br />

settlement as quickly as possible so as to contain costs; and to her client. While <strong>the</strong><br />

employer has means at its disposal to ensure that its interests are accommodated, <strong>the</strong><br />

client does not have a voice: his or her preferences do not exert any financial influence on<br />

<strong>the</strong> attorney. Conversely, <strong>the</strong> staff attorney may face an incentive to draw a case out over<br />

a protracted period of time in order to avoid taking on new work, a decision which may<br />

not actually be in <strong>the</strong> client’s best interests, and over which <strong>the</strong> client can exert only<br />

limited control. <strong>The</strong> above characterization is an exaggeration of <strong>the</strong> likely consequences<br />

of <strong>the</strong> principal-agent dilemma presented by <strong>the</strong> salaried staff model. It does, however,<br />

illustrate <strong>the</strong> need to assure some accountability on <strong>the</strong> part of <strong>the</strong> attorney to her client,<br />

accountability which may be assured by giving <strong>the</strong> consumer direct choice with respect to<br />

his or her legal service provider.<br />

Supply-side subsidies<br />

While <strong>the</strong> basic transaction underlying supply-side subsidization of legal services—<strong>the</strong><br />

government pays <strong>for</strong> services provided by a private lawyer or firm, or community

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!