08.06.2013 Views

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Rethinking</strong> <strong>the</strong> selfare state 190<br />

states. <strong>The</strong> result is typically increasing numbers of low-skilled and <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e structurally<br />

unemployed workers, or wage pressures such as will permit <strong>the</strong> less skilled to retain a<br />

semblance of employment on condition of sharply reduced circumstances.<br />

Even more troubling, key demographic groups often face disproportionate losses. For<br />

instance, in Canada and <strong>the</strong> United <strong>State</strong>s as well as in <strong>the</strong> OECD overall, <strong>the</strong> youth<br />

unemployment rate is roughly double <strong>the</strong> aggregate figure. 17 In addition, women in North<br />

America face an unemployment rate 1.36 times higher than that of men. Recent<br />

immigrants are also typically among <strong>the</strong> most unemployed, in some cases as a result of<br />

poor skill assessment by employers ra<strong>the</strong>r than limited skills per se. 18 Although<br />

unemployment rates vary greatly across different education levels, <strong>the</strong> disparity in<br />

unemployment levels between <strong>the</strong> best-educated quartile and <strong>the</strong> worst-educated quartile<br />

has grown steadily across <strong>the</strong> OECD.<br />

Structural unemployment poses a complex problem <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> underlying rationales <strong>for</strong><br />

government intervention—and is thus primarily responsible <strong>for</strong> framing our focus as one<br />

of government intervention in labour market training. As a starting premise, in <strong>the</strong><br />

acquisition and development of job-related skills, employers should be willing to pay <strong>for</strong><br />

training that is firm specific and employees should be willing to pay <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> acquisition of<br />

general human capital. 19 <strong>The</strong>re are several reasons, however, <strong>for</strong> assuming that employers<br />

and employees will be unable to make optimal decisions about investments in training—<br />

thus providing a rationale <strong>for</strong> government intervention. First is <strong>the</strong> existence of<br />

bargaining failures between employer and employee as to who will bear <strong>the</strong> costs of<br />

training and in what amount. Second, <strong>the</strong> problem of human capital market failure also<br />

arises in this context much as it does in <strong>the</strong> primary, secondary and post-secondary<br />

education contexts. 20 Third, <strong>the</strong>re are externalities associated with training that are<br />

unlikely to be captured fully by <strong>the</strong> private investor. Finally, several government policies<br />

cause marketbased labour market training decisions to be sub-optimal, and may <strong>the</strong>re<strong>for</strong>e<br />

make government intervention through ALMPs a “second-best” response.<br />

Bargaining failure<br />

<strong>The</strong>re are several important complications that can lead to <strong>the</strong> benefits of training not<br />

accruing to those who have incurred <strong>the</strong> costs of training. First, most job training<br />

programs provide participants with increases to both <strong>the</strong>ir firm-specific and general<br />

human capital. Because it is very difficult <strong>for</strong> employers and employees to accurately<br />

measure or apportion <strong>the</strong> shares of general and firm-specific learning that will emerge<br />

from a particular type of training, it may prove difficult to reach agreement on who<br />

should bear <strong>the</strong> costs of training. 21 Second, even if employers and employees can arrange<br />

training such that <strong>the</strong>y each pay <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> benefits that <strong>the</strong>y will receive, employers face a<br />

poaching problem to <strong>the</strong> extent that o<strong>the</strong>r employers, given that <strong>the</strong>y have not had to<br />

incur training costs that have yielded industry-relevant benefits, can af<strong>for</strong>d to entice<br />

trained employees away from <strong>the</strong>ir original employer with higher wages. 22 As Gunderson<br />

notes, “To avoid losing <strong>the</strong>ir trained employee, <strong>the</strong> firm that provided <strong>the</strong> training would<br />

have to pay <strong>the</strong> higher competitive wages. As such, <strong>the</strong>y would double pay by paying <strong>for</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> training and paying <strong>the</strong> higher wage to keep <strong>the</strong> trained employee.” 23 Consequently<br />

employers are likely to under-invest in training that has some benefits that accrue solely<br />

to <strong>the</strong> employee and similarly employees are likely to under-invest in training that has

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!