08.06.2013 Views

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Health care 119<br />

redeem <strong>the</strong> government funding. <strong>The</strong> need <strong>for</strong> baseline safety and quality standards is of<br />

particular importance in <strong>the</strong> domain of LTC, as consumers are, by definition, vulnerable.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>r, as Geron notes, “<strong>for</strong> those consumers who are unable or ill-prepared to take on<br />

<strong>the</strong>se tasks [choosing providers], too much choice may not result in greater<br />

independence—but ra<strong>the</strong>r in a sense of powerlessness.” 119 A regulatory framework <strong>for</strong><br />

setting baseline standards will help to alleviate <strong>the</strong> concern that <strong>the</strong>se individuals will<br />

receive inadequate care in a consumer-directed system.<br />

Geron suggests that an appropriate LTC delivery model should contain both regulated<br />

standards of safety and quality as well as consumer-derived quality measures. This would<br />

include <strong>the</strong> implementation of sector-wide safety standards because “quality problems are<br />

not eliminated when consumers are given <strong>the</strong> responsibility to determine <strong>the</strong> quality<br />

standards <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir care.” 120 However, consumers should be able to control <strong>the</strong>ir care to a<br />

large extent, particularly in <strong>the</strong> case of non-medical home-based services where concerns<br />

about safety are limited, by defining <strong>the</strong>ir own standards of quality and retaining <strong>the</strong><br />

freedom to hire and fire caregivers pursuant to <strong>the</strong>se standards.<br />

Extra billing<br />

A final issue that arises in designing a voucher regime is that of extra billing or “topping<br />

up.” Here <strong>the</strong> issue to be confronted is whe<strong>the</strong>r individuals should be free to negotiate <strong>for</strong><br />

services above <strong>the</strong> minimum standard (assuming a minimum standard can be defined).<br />

Specifically, <strong>the</strong> question arises as to whe<strong>the</strong>r patients should be permitted to use voucher<br />

entitlements as a credit towards higher quality, more expensive or more expeditious<br />

essential services and pay <strong>the</strong> difference <strong>the</strong>mselves, or alternatively opt out of <strong>the</strong> system<br />

altoge<strong>the</strong>r. Again, <strong>the</strong> familiar efficiency versus equity trade-off arises. Prohibiting extra<br />

billing <strong>for</strong> basic covered services suppresses <strong>the</strong> price system and its value as a signal of<br />

and reward <strong>for</strong> superior quality, although permitting it is likely to seriously compromise<br />

equality of access goals and perhaps attenuate <strong>the</strong> political efficacy of voice in<br />

maintaining <strong>the</strong> value of basic voucher entitlements. Extra billing has traditionally been<br />

prohibited in Canada out of concern that those with <strong>the</strong> ability to do so would essentially<br />

exit <strong>the</strong> publicly financed health care system in favour of a superior, largely privately<br />

financed one. <strong>The</strong> public system left behind would <strong>the</strong>n lose <strong>the</strong> support of those<br />

individuals with <strong>the</strong> political voice necessary to ensure <strong>the</strong> maintenance of high-quality<br />

health care delivery. Conventional wisdom in Canada asserts that <strong>for</strong>cing <strong>the</strong> entire<br />

population to put <strong>the</strong>ir health in <strong>the</strong> hands of <strong>the</strong> public system ensures that those with<br />

sufficient political voice will use it to ensure <strong>the</strong>ir own well-being and thus, by extension,<br />

<strong>the</strong> well-being of all. In this respect, <strong>the</strong> system is seen as an important expression of<br />

social, even national solidarity. Although this line of reasoning has some cogency to it, it<br />

is arguable that at least some tailoring of services to meet individual preferences could be<br />

permitted without compromising <strong>the</strong> quality of <strong>the</strong> publicly financed system—especially<br />

given that in some ways, a two-tiered system already exists in Canada as <strong>the</strong> wealthy can<br />

pay <strong>for</strong> additional services, <strong>for</strong> example, private nurses, private hospital rooms or<br />

traveling to <strong>the</strong> United <strong>State</strong>s and making use of US facilities and physicians. 121<br />

Implementing a “topping up” tax, <strong>for</strong> example, as suggested by Sherry Glied 122 is one<br />

means by which this could be achieved. With such a tax in place, individuals who choose<br />

to do so would be permitted to purchase health care services whose value exceeded <strong>the</strong>

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!