08.06.2013 Views

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Food stamps 47<br />

in turn could be utilized at <strong>the</strong>ir discretion to purchase food. Most Western nations have<br />

embraced this policy and, with <strong>the</strong> notable exception of <strong>the</strong> United <strong>State</strong>s, do not<br />

distinguish between cash transfers <strong>for</strong> food and welfare support payments, which are<br />

intended to subsume <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>mer. <strong>The</strong> third option is <strong>the</strong> food stamp or “voucher.” This<br />

option lies somewhere between <strong>the</strong> in-kind benefit and <strong>the</strong> untied benefit. Though <strong>the</strong><br />

family is provided with stamps to purchase food ra<strong>the</strong>r than with actual food, <strong>the</strong> stamps<br />

can be redeemed only <strong>for</strong> approved food products and nothing else. What follows is a<br />

critical analysis of <strong>the</strong>se three options that reveals <strong>the</strong> advantages and disadvantages of<br />

each. It suggests that <strong>the</strong> untied transfer would be <strong>the</strong> most effective means of delivering<br />

assistance with <strong>the</strong> voucher method ranking as <strong>the</strong> next best alternative.<br />

In-kind provision<br />

Although <strong>the</strong> CDP was replaced many years ago by a food stamp regime, <strong>the</strong> benefits of<br />

<strong>the</strong> direct distribution of food commodities to households should not be discounted. <strong>The</strong><br />

most important of <strong>the</strong>se is <strong>the</strong> alleged assurance that food is indeed consumed by <strong>the</strong><br />

family. Unlike cash transfers, it is claimed, in-kind benefits provide recipients with no<br />

alternative uses <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> transfer. Barring <strong>the</strong> evolution of an elaborate underground<br />

economy <strong>for</strong> food, <strong>the</strong> recipients must ei<strong>the</strong>r accept <strong>the</strong> food <strong>the</strong>y are provided with or go<br />

hungry. Given that <strong>the</strong> goal of <strong>the</strong> tax-funded assistance is to reduce food inadequacy, it<br />

is not unreasonable that <strong>the</strong> state and its taxpayers expect that assistance be spent on food<br />

and not on what <strong>the</strong>y perceive to be less essential <strong>for</strong>ms of consumption. If <strong>the</strong> claim that<br />

recipients of cash transfers would not allocate <strong>the</strong> entire value of <strong>the</strong> transfer on food has<br />

any merit, <strong>the</strong>n in-kind provision is desirable from a paternalistic point of view. 28 This<br />

point is particularly relevant when principal-agent issues arise, that is, when <strong>the</strong> recipients<br />

of cash transfers are parents who choose to under-invest in food <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir children. If this<br />

under-investment translates into <strong>the</strong> purchase of low-quality food, though such food may<br />

address <strong>the</strong> immediate concern of hunger, <strong>the</strong> resultant undernourishment will ultimately<br />

lead to long-term costs. A fur<strong>the</strong>r advantage of an in-kind benefit scheme is its decreased<br />

susceptibility to fraud and abuse. Were qualifiers <strong>for</strong> food assistance simply provided<br />

with untied benefits in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>m of monthly government cheques, many who do not suffer<br />

from food inadequacy may go to considerable lengths to gain entry into <strong>the</strong> program.<br />

However, at least intuitively, it seems rational that fewer individuals would make such<br />

false claims if <strong>the</strong> consequent pay-off were food. Finally, <strong>the</strong> assurance of consumption<br />

and <strong>the</strong> reduction of false eligibility claims make in-kind transfers politically appealing.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re are, of course, several disadvantages to <strong>the</strong> direct provision of food<br />

commodities, disadvantages that ultimately <strong>for</strong>med <strong>the</strong> basis <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> replacement of <strong>the</strong><br />

CDP. First, <strong>the</strong> implementation of any such distribution program would require a<br />

significant investment in infrastructure by <strong>the</strong> state. Warehouses would have to be built,<br />

delivery trucks purchased, and employees hired, all of which would contribute to<br />

overhead costs. <strong>The</strong>se costs would be in addition to <strong>the</strong> administrative costs common to<br />

all three regimes (government offices assessing applications and allocating benefits).<br />

Second, many food commodities are perishable; thus unlike a cash payment, it would not<br />

be feasible to make deliveries only once a month. Instead, <strong>the</strong> government supplier would<br />

have to make food available to each household on a more frequent basis. This too would

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!