08.06.2013 Views

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Rethinking</strong> <strong>the</strong> selfare state 160<br />

Ano<strong>the</strong>r set of difficult design issues relates to whe<strong>the</strong>r vouchers should be of fixed or<br />

variable value. If vouchers are of fixed value, <strong>the</strong>n suppliers can be expected to “creamskim”<br />

children who are relatively easy (and less expensive) to educate, while eschewing<br />

children who require additional and/or more complex (and hence, more expensive)<br />

services because <strong>the</strong>y are gifted, learning disabled or come from disadvantaged<br />

socioeconomic backgrounds. 154<br />

One possible response would be to allow <strong>for</strong> unlimited-value vouchers, but this would<br />

generate moral hazard problems on <strong>the</strong> part of demanders and suppliers, who can<br />

externalize <strong>the</strong> cost of expensive education onto <strong>the</strong> state. Alternatively, a complex<br />

scheme of calibrated vouchers that are adjusted by class of student and carry different but<br />

limited values could be created. Most public education systems do, in fact, provide<br />

differential subsidies to schools accepting special-needs students, but <strong>the</strong>se values are not<br />

explicit and are embedded within <strong>the</strong> system’s operating budget. While rendering <strong>the</strong>se<br />

subsidies explicit has <strong>the</strong> advantage of transparency, it also risks invidious political<br />

debates about “pricing (commodifying) <strong>the</strong> price-less.” 155 However, <strong>the</strong>se values could be<br />

suppressed by creating different categories of vouchers without making <strong>the</strong> cost<br />

implications explicit.<br />

As discussed in <strong>the</strong> context of early-childhood education, an alternative mechanism to<br />

address cream-skimming is mandatory pooling. If schools were required to enroll every<br />

student who wished to attend (or in <strong>the</strong> case of over-subscription, hold a random lottery<br />

<strong>for</strong> positions), as is <strong>the</strong> case with charter schools, <strong>the</strong>n it would be more equitable to<br />

simply assign a standard voucher value per student that allows <strong>for</strong> internal crosssubsidization.<br />

156 Instead of trying to deal with <strong>the</strong> subtleties and nuances of valuation in<br />

each individual case, we could rest assured that on average each school is receiving<br />

approximately <strong>the</strong> appropriate level of per-student remuneration. One negative aspect to<br />

this standard voucher value regime, however, might be that this may attenuate <strong>the</strong><br />

emergence of specialized schools oriented towards meeting <strong>the</strong> needs of higher-cost,<br />

more resource-intensive students.<br />

Ano<strong>the</strong>r possible design response is to preclude <strong>for</strong>-profit suppliers from participating<br />

in <strong>the</strong> voucher program. <strong>The</strong> belief is that by limiting participating institutions to those<br />

which are organized solely on a non-profit basis, <strong>the</strong> incentive <strong>for</strong> cream-skimming will<br />

be correspondingly reduced, and, as a consequence, <strong>the</strong> fixed-value voucher model<br />

becomes more plausible. <strong>The</strong> difficulty, however, is in knowing with certainty that non<strong>for</strong>-profit<br />

institutions will necessarily be less inclined to cream-skim. Brad<strong>for</strong>d and<br />

Shaviro liken <strong>the</strong> incentive structure of a non-profit organization to a black box,<br />

contending that <strong>the</strong> objective functions of non-profit organizations cannot be modeled<br />

accurately 157 Notwithstanding this view, it is wrong to take it to an extreme. It is unlikely<br />

that non-profit institutions are irrational—<strong>the</strong>y simply do not respond as predictably to<br />

various incentives as profit-seeking organizations. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, non-profit<br />

organizations have complex utility functions. None<strong>the</strong>less, non-profit educational<br />

institutions likely derive utility, inter alia, from providing a high-quality education to as<br />

many children as possible while meeting <strong>the</strong>ir budget constraints. It is arguable that,<br />

consequently, wherever <strong>the</strong>y can save money <strong>the</strong>y will strive to do so—not because <strong>the</strong>y<br />

seek to make a higher profit, but because <strong>the</strong>y will be able to educate more students better<br />

and <strong>the</strong>reby better fulfil <strong>the</strong>ir mandate. Thus, <strong>the</strong>y may in practice engage in creamskimming<br />

and to a lesser extent, chiselling activities that are often attributed to profit-

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!