08.06.2013 Views

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Rethinking</strong> <strong>the</strong> selfare state 20<br />

ei<strong>the</strong>r or both parties—<strong>the</strong> provider and <strong>the</strong> consumer—to produce or consume<br />

efficiently. <strong>The</strong> lack of innovation in <strong>the</strong> menu of public services can also be seen as a<br />

consequence of <strong>the</strong> failure to provide adequate contractual incentives <strong>for</strong> innovation, as<br />

well as of <strong>the</strong> very structure of certain contractual arrangements, as <strong>for</strong> example in<br />

situations where <strong>the</strong> precise terms of service provision must be negotiated ex ante and<br />

cannot change to meet <strong>the</strong> actual preferences of consumers.<br />

Agency costs<br />

<strong>The</strong>re are also a set of challenges called principal-agent problems: scenarios in which<br />

one party (<strong>the</strong> agent) acts on behalf of ano<strong>the</strong>r (<strong>the</strong> principal), such as when a government<br />

(<strong>the</strong> agent) contracts with a private company to provide services to consumers (<strong>the</strong><br />

principals). In such scenarios, problems will arise <strong>for</strong> two major reasons: it is impossible<br />

<strong>for</strong> even <strong>the</strong> most well-in<strong>for</strong>med agent to have complete knowledge of <strong>the</strong> principal’s<br />

interests and preferences; and <strong>the</strong> preferences of principal and agent may be divergent,<br />

sometimes radically so. 20 <strong>The</strong> <strong>for</strong>mer problem is sometimes described (most famously by<br />

Friedman 21 ) as paternalism; that is, <strong>the</strong> arrogation to <strong>the</strong> agent of <strong>the</strong> right to decide what<br />

is in <strong>the</strong> best interests of a rational and self-aware principal who may actually be in a far<br />

better position to discern what is best insofar as his or her own welfare is concerned. <strong>The</strong><br />

latter problem can manifest itself in a variety of <strong>for</strong>ms, from <strong>the</strong> development of policies<br />

which are unpalatable to consumers, to overt conflicts of interest, such as patronage and<br />

bribery.<br />

Modes of accountability<br />

As serious as certain principal-agent conflicts can be, a variety of mechanisms or modes<br />

of accountability operate in both <strong>the</strong> public and private sectors to align <strong>the</strong> interests of<br />

principals and agents. <strong>The</strong>se mechanisms become particularly important in scenarios<br />

which are not explicitly covered by <strong>the</strong> terms of contract. However, <strong>the</strong>se mechanisms<br />

are not all equally effective, and can give rise to agency costs, such as “<strong>the</strong> cost of<br />

structuring <strong>the</strong> contract so as to require <strong>the</strong> agent to per<strong>for</strong>m <strong>the</strong> desired service as a<br />

proxy <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> principal [and] <strong>the</strong> cost of en<strong>for</strong>cing <strong>the</strong> contract.” 22 As Trebilcock<br />

observes, “[d]ifferent organizational arrangements have different inherent incentive<br />

structures that yield different agency costs.” 23<br />

For instance, in organizations with a diffuse body of principals, such as publicly traded<br />

companies with a large number of stockholders, <strong>the</strong> principals face a problem in asserting<br />

control over <strong>the</strong> company, since <strong>the</strong>y can only exert pressure on <strong>the</strong>ir agent (<strong>the</strong><br />

company’s management) by acting collectively. At <strong>the</strong> same time, however, <strong>the</strong> “market<br />

<strong>for</strong> managers” and <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> hiring of management is often based on <strong>the</strong> track<br />

record of candidates with respect to stock per<strong>for</strong>mance, can help to align <strong>the</strong> interests of<br />

<strong>the</strong> principals and <strong>the</strong>ir agents. 24 Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, remuneration in <strong>the</strong> <strong>for</strong>m of stock or stock<br />

options creates a direct incentive on <strong>the</strong> part of management to improve <strong>the</strong> company’s<br />

market per<strong>for</strong>mance, and <strong>the</strong> wealth of stockholders along with it. Public enterprises,<br />

however, are not as directly affected by management markets, and must rely on still o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

modes of accountability, with different <strong>for</strong>ms of agency costs.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!