08.06.2013 Views

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Rethinking</strong> <strong>the</strong> selfare state 54<br />

<strong>the</strong> recipient. A household that is truly in need of food would most likely prefer not to<br />

trade <strong>the</strong> vouchers <strong>for</strong> cash. It is <strong>the</strong> individuals that falsely make <strong>the</strong>mselves eligible <strong>for</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> program or non-autonomous agents (i.e. alcoholics or drug addicts) that can be<br />

expected to engage in trafficking.<br />

Although <strong>the</strong> USDA oversees <strong>the</strong> retail outlets that are participating in <strong>the</strong> program, it<br />

remains difficult to measure <strong>the</strong> precise extent of abuse and fraud within <strong>the</strong> FSP One<br />

USDA official told Time Magazine in 1982 that “<strong>the</strong> [food stamp] coupons are a second<br />

currency. Anything that you can buy with money… you can buy with food stamps.” 68<br />

Although this may be an exaggeration, it is plausible to expect that some individuals will<br />

be willing to exchange food stamps <strong>for</strong> less than face value cash payments. Again, <strong>the</strong><br />

trade-off in trying to reduce such illegal behaviour is <strong>the</strong> additional cost of doing so. In<br />

terms of efficiency, <strong>the</strong> government must assess <strong>the</strong> costs of prevention versus <strong>the</strong> costs<br />

of non-prevention. Preventative measures, such as putting <strong>the</strong> recipient through a<br />

rigorous eligibility determination process or stricter authorization guidelines <strong>for</strong> retail<br />

stores, result not only in higher administrative costs but also may reduce participation<br />

rates and accessibility.<br />

Notwithstanding <strong>the</strong> overall authorization process, Robert A.Moffitt notes that <strong>the</strong>re<br />

are over 200,000 participating retail outlets in <strong>the</strong> United <strong>State</strong>s. 69 <strong>The</strong> large number of<br />

authorized outlets indicates that <strong>the</strong> process is not very restrictive with regards to<br />

supermarkets and convenience stores. Given <strong>the</strong> large monthly payouts to recipients, <strong>the</strong><br />

supply-side enjoys significant benefits from <strong>the</strong> FSP only if <strong>the</strong>y are not cash equivalent.<br />

However, based on data collected in 1987, <strong>the</strong> USDA estimated that a reduction in <strong>the</strong><br />

FSP by $1 billion would lead to a loss of 25,000 jobs. 70 Thus, suppliers have a vested<br />

interest in <strong>the</strong> continuance of <strong>the</strong> FSP.<br />

<strong>The</strong> value of <strong>the</strong> voucher<br />

Once a household qualifies <strong>for</strong> assistance, <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong> food stamps granted is a<br />

function of net income. Net income is calculated by deducting expenses such as medical<br />

(<strong>for</strong> elderly and disabled only) and dependent care (if an adult member is working or<br />

training and has children) from gross income. 71 <strong>The</strong> program assumes that <strong>the</strong><br />

participating household will devote 30 percent of this “net income” to food purchases.<br />

<strong>The</strong> monetary difference between <strong>the</strong> expected contribution by <strong>the</strong> recipient and <strong>the</strong><br />

government-determined cost of purchasing a “nutritionally adequate low-cost diet” given<br />

<strong>the</strong> household size establishes <strong>the</strong> precise value of <strong>the</strong> food stamps. 72 Embedded within<br />

such a structure is an upper limit or cap on benefits received. For example, a household<br />

with an income of zero will receive <strong>the</strong> maximum level of benefits based on <strong>the</strong> cost of<br />

an adequate diet but no more. <strong>The</strong> maximum benefit, however, varies according to<br />

household size and is adjusted annually <strong>for</strong> changes in <strong>the</strong> benchmark diet. In 1995, a<br />

single-person household was eligible <strong>for</strong> a maximum of $115 of coupons per month. 73<br />

For a household of eight, <strong>the</strong> corresponding benefit was $695. 74<br />

An important element of <strong>the</strong> FSP is that <strong>the</strong> unit of focus is not <strong>the</strong> individual but <strong>the</strong><br />

household. <strong>The</strong> maximum allowable benefit increases as <strong>the</strong> number of family members<br />

increases; however, this increase is not proportional. Each member of a family of four,<br />

<strong>for</strong> instance, does not receive <strong>the</strong> amount that a single-member household would receive.<br />

While at first glance this might seem inconsistent with horizontal equity—<strong>the</strong> system

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!