08.06.2013 Views

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

Rethinking the Welfare State: The prospects for ... - e-Library

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Food stamps 55<br />

seems to discriminate against households with multiple members—<strong>the</strong>re is a rational<br />

basis <strong>for</strong> this apparent “discrimination.” That is, <strong>the</strong> average food cost per person<br />

decreases as <strong>the</strong> number of members in a household increases because of economies of<br />

scale in <strong>the</strong> purchasing and preparation of food. <strong>The</strong> focus on <strong>the</strong> household thus enables<br />

<strong>the</strong> government to adjust <strong>for</strong> <strong>the</strong> decreasing marginal cost of feeding additional household<br />

members. A significant drawback of this household unit analysis, however, is its inability<br />

to adjust to specific demographics within <strong>the</strong> household. All things being equal, a<br />

household with two teenage boys will receive <strong>the</strong> same amount of food stamps as a<br />

family with two infants.<br />

Political considerations<br />

Notwithstanding its critics, <strong>the</strong> FSP design has survived numerous presidential<br />

administrations, both Democratic and Republican. Never<strong>the</strong>less, two re<strong>for</strong>m proposals,<br />

“cost-shifting” and “cashing-out,” have been at <strong>the</strong> centre of debates throughout <strong>the</strong><br />

1990s.<br />

Fundamental to a thorough appreciation of <strong>the</strong> cost-shifting debate is an understanding<br />

of <strong>the</strong> current financing of <strong>the</strong> FSP. <strong>The</strong> FSP is a federal program such that 100 percent of<br />

benefits are paid <strong>for</strong> by <strong>the</strong> federal government out of general tax revenues. However, <strong>the</strong><br />

program is administered locally by <strong>the</strong> states, each of which pay approximately 50<br />

percent of local administrative costs. Given that <strong>the</strong> program has been mandatory since<br />

1973, <strong>the</strong>re have been ef<strong>for</strong>ts to shift <strong>the</strong> responsibility (and a higher burden of costs) on<br />

to <strong>the</strong> states. As such, <strong>the</strong> federal government would only be responsible <strong>for</strong> providing set<br />

block grants to <strong>the</strong> states—which by nature do not adjust to economic fluctuations—<br />

instead of having to pay <strong>the</strong> face value of <strong>the</strong> vouchers.<br />

Not only have social advocacy groups resisted <strong>the</strong> cost-shifting proposal, but so has<br />

<strong>the</strong> powerful agriculture lobby (both <strong>the</strong> farming and retail sectors). This latter group<br />

stands to lose out in any cost-shifting arrangement <strong>for</strong> if <strong>the</strong> states assume greater control<br />

of <strong>the</strong> program, it is likely that <strong>the</strong>y will redesign <strong>the</strong> program to cut costs. <strong>The</strong> fear of<br />

<strong>the</strong>se interest groups is that <strong>the</strong> future aggregate expenditure by <strong>the</strong> states will be less<br />

than <strong>the</strong> current national expenditure on <strong>the</strong> FSP. This fear may be well grounded; as<br />

mentioned earlier, a USDA report in 1995 indicated that a reduction in funding of <strong>the</strong><br />

FSP by one billion dollars would eliminate 25,000 jobs. It is in part because of <strong>the</strong><br />

strength of this interest group that <strong>the</strong> FSP remains one of <strong>the</strong> last welfare programs<br />

wholly financed by <strong>the</strong> federal government.<br />

<strong>The</strong> second debated option, “cashing-out,” would also involve <strong>the</strong> provision of block<br />

grants by <strong>the</strong> federal government to <strong>the</strong> states. Under this scheme, however, <strong>the</strong> states<br />

would not be obliged to continue <strong>the</strong> FSP. Instead, <strong>the</strong> state could “cash-out” <strong>the</strong> program<br />

by replacing <strong>the</strong> stamps with general income assistance. <strong>The</strong> arguments favouring this<br />

option are, of course, lower administrative costs and reduction in stigma.<br />

<strong>The</strong> political concern with <strong>the</strong> “cashing-out” option is that it would severely hurt <strong>the</strong><br />

interests of those in need. Cashing-out <strong>the</strong> program leaves <strong>the</strong> states just one step away<br />

from amalgamating <strong>the</strong> food stamp benefits with o<strong>the</strong>r state-financed programs such as<br />

TANF. In creating one welfare payment, critics argue that <strong>the</strong> state will be inclined to cut<br />

<strong>the</strong> total benefits allotted. <strong>The</strong> aggregate benefits to a low-income earner under a lumpsum<br />

regime would thus place individuals in more vulnerable positions than <strong>the</strong>y are in

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!