07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

4.1 The price responsiveness of demand<br />

Using ( 4) you can find the elasticity at any point of a demand curve, linear or non-linear. There are special cases<br />

in which the elasticity is constant along a demand curve. Consider the following direct demand function:<br />

Q D = 100<br />

p<br />

The demand function in (5) is non-linear (try to plot it!). In this case, the derivative of the direct demand is:<br />

dQV 100<br />

-- =--<br />

dP P2<br />

Suppose we want to know the elasticity of demand at P = 5. At that price the quantity demanded according to<br />

(5) is Q0 = 20. In this case, we have dQ0!dp = -[100/(5)2] = -4. Applying equation (4) we have:<br />

5<br />

PED =-4-=-l<br />

20<br />

(5)<br />

at P = 5 the demand is unit elastic. What about at P = 10? In this case, the<br />

quantity demanded is Q0 = 100/10 = 10 and then dQ0!dp = -[100/(10)2] =<br />

-1. The PED is:<br />

If the demand elasticity is -1 ,<br />

demand is unit elastic.<br />

10<br />

PED =-1-=-l<br />

10<br />

the PED is still -1. Indeed, any demand function of the form Q 0 =Al P, where A is any positive constant, has<br />

the property that the elasticity of demand is constant along the demand curve.<br />

Determinants of price elasticity<br />

Why is the price elasticity of demand for a good high (-5) or low (-0.5)? The answer lies in consumer<br />

tastes. If it is a social necessity to own a television, higher TV prices have little effect on quantity demanded.<br />

IfTV s are considered a frivolous luxury, the demand elasticity is much higher. Psychologists and sociologists<br />

can explain why tastes are as they are. As economists, we can identify some considerations likely to affect<br />

consumer responses to changes in the price of a good. The most important consideration is the ease with<br />

which consumers can substitute another good that fulfils approximately the same function.<br />

Consider two extreme cases. Suppose the price of all cigarettes rises by 1 per cent. The quantity of cigarettes<br />

demanded will hardly respond. People who can easily quit smoking have already done so. In contrast,<br />

suppose the price of a particular brand of cigarettes rises by 1 per cent, all other brand prices remaining<br />

unchanged. We expect a much larger quantity response. Consumers switch from the dearer brand to other<br />

brands that also satisfy the nicotine habit. For a particular cigarette brand the demand elasticity is quite high.<br />

Our example suggests a general rule. The more narrowly we define a commodity (a particular brand of<br />

cigarette rather than cigarettes in general), the higher will be the price elasticity of demand.<br />

Measuring price elasticities<br />

Table 4.2 confirms that the demand for broad categories of basic commodities, such as fuel, food or even<br />

services to household, is inelastic. As a category, only alcohol seems to have an elastic demand. Households<br />

simply do not have much scope to alter the broad pattern of their purchases.<br />

71

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!