07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

CHAPTER 25 Open economy macroeconomics<br />

Capital controls are<br />

regulations preventing private<br />

sector capital flows be1ween<br />

different currencies.<br />

Most economies had capital controls during the period of fixed exchange rates<br />

from 1945 to 1973. Subsequent integration of global financial markets made these<br />

controls less effective and now they have been scrapped.<br />

With a fixed exchange rate but no private capital flows, suppose the economy has<br />

a balance of payments deficit (because it has a current account deficit). To finance<br />

the deficit, the forex reserves must fall. The central bank sells foreign exchange and buys domestic currency,<br />

demanding the domestic currency that nobody else wants. In consequence, domestic money in circulation<br />

falls as pounds disappear back into the Bank of England. The balance of payments deficit reduces the<br />

domestic money supply. A balance of payments surplus would increase the money supply.<br />

Under fixed exchange rates, the money supply is not determined exclusively by the original decision about<br />

how much domestic money to create. It also depends on the balance of payments surplus or deficit. When<br />

there is a payments surplus (deficit), cash flows into (out of) the country, directly changing narrow money,<br />

which in turn affects bank deposits and broad money.<br />

Unsterilized intervention<br />

uses the forex reserves to offset<br />

balance of payments surpluses<br />

or deficits. Since foreign<br />

reserves are exchanged for<br />

domestic cash, this alters the<br />

cash in circulation and the<br />

domestic money supply.<br />

Sterilization is an open<br />

market operation be1ween<br />

domestic money and domestic<br />

bonds, to offset the change in<br />

domestic money supply that<br />

a balance of payments surplus<br />

or deficit otherwise induces.<br />

IS<br />

J _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _<br />

II)<br />

G.I<br />

""<br />

G.I<br />

-<br />

c<br />

Output<br />

I<br />

· ·<br />

I<br />

I<br />

I<br />

I<br />

I<br />

I<br />

Figure 25.1 A balance of payments deficit<br />

reduces the money supply and raises interest rates<br />

Allowing the balance of payments to change the money supply is called unsterilized<br />

intervention in the forex market. For a given money demand schedule, allowing<br />

changes in the money supply means then having to change interest rates to make<br />

this an equilibrium.<br />

Figure 25.1 illustrates using the IS-LM model. Initially, the economy faces the IS<br />

curve shown, and its monetary policy is reflected in LM. Short-run equilibrium is<br />

therefore at point A. However, the economy has a current account deficit and<br />

balance of payments deficit. If it allows this to deplete its domestic money supply,<br />

the LM curve will shift to LM', causing a rise in interest rates and a domestic<br />

recession. The economy moves to point B. The recession reduces import demand<br />

and eliminates the current account deficit.<br />

Alternatively, the central bank may create additional domestic money to prevent<br />

the balance of payments deficit reducing the money supply. The LM curve remains<br />

in its original position and the economy remains at<br />

point A.<br />

Although the total money supply is not changing,<br />

something important is happening to the balance<br />

sheet of the central bank. On the liability side, money<br />

supplied is constant. On the asset side, the central<br />

bank holds foreign exchange reserves and government<br />

bonds.<br />

M=R+B<br />

To keep M constant while R is falling, the central<br />

bank is effectively selling foreign exchange and buying<br />

domestic government bonds. It can keep doing so<br />

until R becomes zero, at which point it runs out of<br />

foreign exchange reserves and can no longer keep<br />

financing the balance of payments deficit. If the exchange<br />

rate is not to be devalued, thereafter it requires a<br />

domestic recession to get imports down. This can<br />

be achieved either by allowing the shift in the LM<br />

schedule shown in Figure 25. l or by fiscal action,<br />

for example higher taxes, that shifts the IS schedule<br />

to the left. <strong>Higher</strong> taxes reduce disposable incomes,<br />

reduce aggregate demand, and thereby reduce imports.<br />

572

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!