07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

CHAPTER 4 Elasticities of demand and supply<br />

Table 4.2<br />

UK price elasticities of demand<br />

Good (broad type) Demand elasticity Good (narrow type) Demand elasticity<br />

Fuel and light -0 .52 Bread -0.4<br />

Food -0.56 Fish -0.8<br />

Clothing -0.62 Beer -0 .2<br />

Services -0.72 Expenditure abroad -1 .6<br />

Alcohol -1 .73 Catering -2.6<br />

Sources: Blundell, R., Poshordes, P. and Weber, G. (1 993} What do we learn about consumer demand patterns from micro<br />

data?, American Economic Review, 83 (3): 570-597; Notional Food Survey 2000.<br />

In contrast, there is a much wider variation in the demand elasticities for narrower definitions of<br />

commodities. Even then, the demand for some commodities, such as dairy produce, is very inelastic.<br />

However, particular kinds of services such as catering have much more elastic demand.<br />

Using price elasticities<br />

Price elasticities of demand are useful in calculating the price rise required to eliminate a shortage (excess<br />

demand) or the price fall to eliminate a surplus (excess supply). One important source of surpluses and<br />

shortages is shifts in the supply curve. Harvest failures (and bumper crops) are a feature of agricultural<br />

markets. Because the demand elasticity for many agricultural products is very low, harvest failures produce<br />

large increases in the price of food. Conversely, bumper crops induce very large falls in food prices. When<br />

demand is very inelastic, shifts in the supply curve lead to large fluctuations in price but have little effect<br />

on equilibrium quantities.<br />

Figure 4.3(a) illustrates this. SS is the supply curve in an agricultural market when there is a harvest failure<br />

and S'S' the supply curve when there is a bumper crop. The equilibrium price fluctuates between P1 (harvest<br />

failure) and P2 (bumper crop) but induces little fluctuation in the corresponding equilibrium quantities.<br />

Contrast this with Figure 4.3(b ), which shows the effect of similar supply shifts in a market with very<br />

elastic demand. Price fluctuations are much smaller but quantity fluctuations are now much larger.<br />

Knowing the demand elasticity helps us understand why some markets exhibit volatile quantities but stable<br />

prices, while other markets exhibit volatile prices but stable quantities.<br />

Price, quantity demanded and total expenditure<br />

Other things equal, the demand curve shows how much consumers of a good wish to purchase at each price.<br />

At each price, total spending by consumers is the price multiplied by the quantity demanded. We now discuss<br />

the relationship between total spending and price and show the relevance of the price elasticity of demand.<br />

Figure 4.4 shows how total spending changes with price changes. In case A, we begin at A with price PA and<br />

quantity demanded QA- Total spending is PAQA, the area of the rectangle OPAAQA- At the lower price PB,<br />

consumers demand QB and total spending is P8Q8, the area of the rectangle OP8BQ8. How does total<br />

spending change when prices fall from PA to P8? Spending falls by the area marked (-) but rises by the area<br />

marked ( +). In case A, the ( +) area exceeds the (-) area and total spending rises. In the elastic range of the<br />

demand curve (towards the upper end), a lower price raises the quantity demanded by more than enough<br />

to offset the lower price. Total spending rises.<br />

72

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!