07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

20.2 The IS-LM model<br />

Until 2008 monetary policy had successfully stabilized most countries close to the trend level of normal<br />

output. There was little discrepancy between actual and cyclically-adjusted budgets, because the business<br />

cycle had largely been eliminated. The evolution of the budget position was therefore due to changes in fiscal<br />

policy - decisions about tax rates and spending levels - not fluctuations in output.<br />

For example, in the UK, after 2000 the government embarked on a substantial increase in government<br />

spending, especially on health care. Since tax rates were not raised in line, both the actual and the cyclicallyadjusted<br />

budget deficit increased. Chancellor Gordon Brown was finding it harder and harder to live up to his<br />

claim of fiscal responsibility.<br />

In the years leading up to 2008, the Spanish budget surplus was steadily increasing, and that of Italy was<br />

essentially flat. Italy and Spain were not on a course of fiscal recklessness. Since Greece has subsequently<br />

admitted that all of its official statistics were wrong, changes in Greece probably had more to do with changes<br />

in reporting than in underlying reality.<br />

All four charts confirm that large falls in output in 2009 had immediate and adverse effects on budget deficits.<br />

Not merely did banks require bailouts, but tax revenues fell as activity fell. There are reasons to hope that both<br />

may be reversed as output recovers. Tax revenue will improve and governments may recoup some of the<br />

bailout funds as banks become healthier.<br />

None of this detracts from the fact that substantial tax rises and spending cuts will still be required. Some of the<br />

bank assets are permanently bad, governments have to pay interest on the debts they have issued in the meantime,<br />

and projected output paths (and hence tax revenues) are lower than we had previously been projecting.<br />

All of this affects the decision of when to tighten fiscal policy. If interest rates could be reduced further, fiscal<br />

policy could be tightened immediately without threatening the output recovery. But interest rates are already<br />

close to rock bottom, If fiscal policy is tightened too much too soon, output recovery will stall, tax revenues<br />

will not materialize, and the desired improvement in government finances will be frustrated. However, if<br />

fiscal tightening is postponed too long, government debt will have mushroomed to levels that will then be<br />

very hard to repay. Nobody said economic policy was supposed to be easy.<br />

The LM schedule: money market equilibrium<br />

Pursuing a monetary target, the central bank endeavours to fix the money supply<br />

itself. In Figure 20.2, along the LM schedule, the demand for money (or liquidity,<br />

hence L) equals the given supply of money (hence M). Hence the shorthand LM.<br />

The quantity of money demanded rises with output Y but falls with the interest<br />

rate r. In money market equilibrium, money demand equals the given money<br />

supply. Hence if output rises from Y0 to Y 1 - tending to raise the quantity of money<br />

demanded - money market equilibrium is restored only if interest rates rise from<br />

r0 to rl> thereby reducing money demand back to the level of the given money<br />

The LM schedule shows<br />

combinations of interest rates<br />

and income-yielding money<br />

market equilibrium when the<br />

central bank pursues a given<br />

target for the nominal money<br />

supply.<br />

supply. Figure 20.2 shows the upward-sloping schedule LM describing money market equilibrium. <strong>Higher</strong><br />

output and income are accompanied by higher interest rates.<br />

The slope of the schedule<br />

The LM schedule slopes up. Following a monetary target, higher output induces a higher interest rate to<br />

keep money demand in line with money supply. The more sensitive is money demand to income and output,<br />

the more the interest rate must change to maintain money market equilibrium, and the steeper is the LM<br />

schedule. Similarly, if money demand is not responsive to interest rates, it takes a big change in interest<br />

rates to offset output effects on money demand, and the LM schedule is steep. Conversely, the more money<br />

demand responds to interest rates and the less it responds to income, the flatter is the LM schedule.<br />

467

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!