07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

CHAPTER 22 Inflation, expectations and credibility<br />

Taxes<br />

Tax rates may not be fully inflation-adjusted. One problem is fiscal drag.<br />

Fiscal drag is the rise in real<br />

tax revenue when inflation<br />

raises nominal incomes,<br />

pushing people into higher<br />

tax brackets in a progressive<br />

income tax system.<br />

Suppose income below £4000 is untaxed but you pay income tax at 25 per cent on<br />

all income over that amount. Initially, you earn £5000 and pay income tax of £250.<br />

After ten years of inflation, all wages and prices double but tax brackets and tax rates<br />

remain as before. You now earn £10 000. Paying tax at 25 per cent on the £6000 by<br />

which your nominal income exceeds £4000, you pay nominal tax of £1500. Wages and<br />

prices only doubled, but your nominal tax payment rose from £250 to £1500. Fiscal<br />

drag raised the real tax burden. The government gained from inflation. You lost.<br />

For an inflation-neutral tax system, nominal tax brackets must rise with inflation.<br />

The real tax exemption is constant if the nominal limit rises from £4000 to £8000. Everything is then<br />

inflation-adjusted. You would pay £500 in tax - double what you paid before.<br />

Percentage taxes on value, such as VAT, automatically raise nominal tax revenue in line with the price level.<br />

However, specific duties, such as £5 on a bottle of whisky, must be raised as the price level rises. In the UK<br />

there is no automatic formula for raising such duties. Each year the government decides.<br />

Taxing capital<br />

Income tax on interest income is also affected by inflation. Suppose there is no inflation. Nominal and real<br />

interest rates are both 4 per cent. With a 40 per cent tax rate, the after-tax real return on lending is 2.6 per cent.<br />

Now suppose inflation is 11 per cent and nominal interest rates are 15 per cent to keep a pre-tax real<br />

interest rate of 4 per cent. Suppose lenders must pay income tax on nominal interest income. The after-tax<br />

nominal interest rate is 9 per cent (0.6 x 15). Subtracting 11 per cent inflation, the after-tax real interest rate<br />

is -2 per cent. This compares with +2.6 per cent when inflation was zero.<br />

Inflation accounting<br />

uses fully inflation-adjusted<br />

definitions of costs, income<br />

and profit.<br />

When inflation was 11 per cent, nominal interest rates were 15 per cent. Eleven<br />

per cent of this was not real income, merely a payment to keep up with inflation.<br />

Only 4 per cent was the real interest rate providing real income. But income tax<br />

applied to all 15 per cent. <strong>Higher</strong> inflation reduced the real return on lending<br />

because the tax system was not properly inflation-adjusted, that is, it did not use<br />

inflation accounting. The government gained more real tax revenue. You lost.<br />

Capital gains tax is another example. Suppose people pay tax of 40 per cent on any capital gain made when<br />

asset prices rise. When inflation is zero, only real gains are taxed. When inflation is 10 per cent, nominal<br />

asset prices rise merely to preserve their real value. People pay capital gains tax even though they are not<br />

making real capital gains.<br />

Institutional imperfections help explain why inflation has real effects even when inflation is fully anticipated.<br />

These effects can be large. Usually, the government is the winner.<br />

Unexpected inflation<br />

Previously, we assumed that inflation was fully anticipated. What if inflation is a surprise?<br />

Redistribution<br />

When prices rise unexpectedly, people with nominal assets lose and people with nominal liabilities gain.<br />

Nominal contracts to buy and sell, or lend and borrow, can reflect expected inflation, but cannot reflect<br />

surprise inflation.<br />

Expecting inflation of 10 per cent, you lend £100 for a year at 12 per cent, expecting a real interest rate of<br />

2 per cent. Unexpectedly, inflation is 20 per cent. The real interest rate on your loan is [ 12 - 20] = -8 per cent.<br />

516

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!