07.09.2017 Views

David K.H. Begg, Gianluigi Vernasca-Economics-McGraw Hill Higher Education (2011)

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

12.2 Insurance and risk<br />

Life assurance companies take in premium payments in exchange for a promise to pay a large amount to<br />

the family if the insured person dies. The company can make this promise with great certainty because it<br />

pools risks over many clients. Since the company cannot guarantee that exactly 1 per cent of its many<br />

55-year-olds will die in any one year, there is a small element of residual risk for the company to bear, and<br />

it makes a small charge for this in calculating its premiums. However, the company's ability to pool the risk<br />

means that it will make only a small charge. If life assurance companies try to charge more, new entrants<br />

join the industry knowing that the profits more than compensate for the small residual risk to be borne.<br />

Risk pooling does not work when all individuals face the same risk. Suppose there<br />

is a 10 per cent risk of a nuclear war in Europe in the next ten years. If it happens,<br />

everyone in Europe dies, leaving money to their nearest surviving relative in the<br />

rest of the world. Ten million people in Western Europe offer to buy insurance<br />

from an American company.<br />

Risk pooling aggregates<br />

independent risks to make<br />

the aggregate more certain.<br />

Despite the number of people, the risk cannot be pooled. If everybody in Europe dies, if anybody dies, the<br />

insurance company either pays out to everybody's relatives or it pays nothing. In the aggregate there is still<br />

a 10 per cent chance of having to pay out, just as individual Europeans face a 10 per cent chance of disaster.<br />

When the same thing happens to everybody, if it happens at all, the aggregate behaves like the individual.<br />

There is no risk reduction from pooling.<br />

Many insurance companies do not insure against what they call 'acts of God' - floods, earthquakes,<br />

epidemics. Such disasters are no more natural or unnatural than a heart attack. But they affect large<br />

numbers of the insurance company's clients if they happen at all. The risk cannot be reduced by pooling.<br />

Companies cannot quote the low premium rates that apply for heart attacks, where risks are independent<br />

and the aggregate outcome is fairly certain.<br />

There is another way to reduce the cost of risk bearing. This is known as risk<br />

sharing, and the most famous example is the Lloyd's insurance market in London.<br />

Risk sharing is necessary when it has proved impossible to reduce the risk by<br />

pooling. Lloyd's offers insurance on earthquakes in California, and insurance of a<br />

film star's legs.<br />

Risk sharing works by<br />

reducing the stake.<br />

To understand risk sharing we return to diminishing marginal utility. We argued that the utility benefit<br />

from an extra £10 000 is less than the utility sacrificed when £10 000 is given up. However, this difference<br />

in marginal utility for equivalent monetary gains and losses is tiny if the size of the stake is tiny. The<br />

marginal utility from an extra £1 is only fractionally less than the utility lost by sacrificing £1. For small<br />

stakes, people are almost risk-neutral. You would probably toss a coin with us to win or lose £0.10, but not<br />

to win or lose £10 000. The larger the stake, the more diminishing marginal utility bites.<br />

You go to Lloyd's to insure the US space shuttle launch for £20 billion - a big risk. Only part of this risk<br />

can be pooled as part of a larger portfolio of risks. It is too big for anyone to take on at a reasonable<br />

premium.<br />

The Lloyd's market in London has hundreds of 'syndicates: each a group of 20 or so individuals who have<br />

each put up £100 000. Each syndicate takes perhaps 1 per cent of the £20 billion deal and then resells the<br />

risk to yet other people in the insurance industry. By the time the deal has been subdivided and subdivided<br />

again, each syndicate or insurance company holds a tiny share of the total. And each syndicate risk is<br />

further subdivided among its 20 members. The risk is shared out until each individual's stake is so small<br />

that there is a tiny difference between the marginal utility from a gain and the marginal loss of utility in the<br />

event of a disaster. It now takes only a small premium to cover this risk. The package can be sold to the<br />

client at a premium low enough to attract the business.<br />

By pooling and sharing risks, insurance allows individuals to deal with many risks at affordable premiums.<br />

But two things inhibit the operation of insurance markets, reducing the extent to which individuals can<br />

use insurance to buy their way out of risky situations.<br />

279

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!